Skip to main content

Pareto Efficiency, Inequality and Distribution Neutral Fiscal Policy—An Overview

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
New Perspectives and Challenges in Econophysics and Sociophysics

Part of the book series: New Economic Windows ((NEW))

Abstract

A structure of taxes and transfers that keep the income distribution unchanged even after positive or negative shocks to an economy, is referred as a Distribution Neutral Fiscal Policy. Marjit and Sarkar (Distribution neutral welfare ranking-extending pareto principle, 2017, [14]) referred this as a Strong Pareto Superior (SPS) allocation which improves the standard Pareto criterion by keeping the degree of inequality, not the absolute level of income, intact. In this paper we show the existence of a SPS allocation in a general equilibrium framework, and we provide a brief survey of distribution neutral fiscal policies existing in the literature. We also provide an empirical illustration with Indian Human Development Survey data.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 109.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Readers interested in this topics are referred to [7,8,9, 21].

  2. 2.

    This can also be interpreted as the desired level of inequality the policy maker is anticipating.

  3. 3.

    Note that per-capita income data is available in this survey. However, income data have standard problems in the sense that people often misreports their income. Furthermore, the poverty line in India is usually constructed using the per-capita consumption figures. Thus using such figures for income data might be incomplete.

  4. 4.

    An Wikipedia entry argues that “It would be incorrect to treat Pareto efficiency as equivalent to societal optimization, as the latter is a normative concept that is a matter of interpretation that typically would account for the consequence of degrees of inequality of distribution.” (https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Pareto_efficiency).

References

  1. Arrow, K.J.: Social Choice and Individual Values, vol. 12. Yale University Press (1963)

    Google Scholar 

  2. Cornes, R., Sandler, T.: Pareto-improving redistribution and pure public goods. Ger. Econ. Rev. 1(2), 169–186 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Datt, G., Ravallion, M.: Growth and redistribution components of changes in poverty measures: A decomposition with applications to brazil and india in the 1980s. J. Dev. Econ. 38(2), 275–295 (1992)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. De Scitovszky, T.: A note on welfare propositions in economics. Rev. Econ. Stud. 9(1), 77–88 (1941)

    Google Scholar 

  5. Duclos, J.Y.: What is pro-poor? Soc. Choice Welf. 58, 32–37 (2009)

    MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  6. Gupta, S., Marjit, S., Sarkar, S.: An application of distribution-neutral fiscal policy. IMF Working Paper No. 18/12 (2018)

    Google Scholar 

  7. Jain, L.R., Tendulkar, S.D.: Role of growth and distribution in the observed change in headcount ratio measure of poverty: a decomposition exercise for india. Indian Econ. Rev. 165–205 (1990)

    Google Scholar 

  8. Kakwani, N., Subbarao, K.: Rural poverty and its alleviation in india. Econ. Polit. Wkly. A2–A16 (1990)

    Google Scholar 

  9. Kakwani, N.: On measuring growth and inequality components of poverty with application to thailand. J. Quant. Econ. 16(1), 67–80 (2000)

    Google Scholar 

  10. Kakwani, N., Pernia, E.: What is pro-poor growth? Asian Dev. Rev. 16, 1–22 (2000)

    Google Scholar 

  11. Kraay, A.: When is growth pro-poor ? evidence from a panel of countries. J. Dev. Econ. 80, 198–222 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Mandler, M.: Simple pareto-improving policies. J. Econ. Theory 84(1), 120–133 (1999)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  13. Marjit, S., Sarkar, S., Yang, L.: Gains from trade, inequality and distribution-neutral fiscal policy. mimeo-CSSSC (2018)

    Google Scholar 

  14. Marjit, S., Sarkar, S.: Distribution neutral welfare ranking-extending pareto principle. CESifo Working Paper No. 6397 (2017)

    Google Scholar 

  15. Marjit, S.: On economics as a physical science. Eur. Phys. J. Spec. Top. 225(17–18), 3269–3273 (2016)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Nssah, E.: A unified framework for pro-poor growth analysis. Econ. Lett. 89, 216–221 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Osmani, S.: Defining pro-poor growth. One Pager Number 9, vol. 9. International Poverty Center, Brazil (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  18. Ravallion, M., Chen, S.: Measuring pro-poor growth. Econ. Lett. 78(1), 93–99 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Samuelson, P.A.: Aspects of public expenditure theories. Rev. Econ. Stat. 332–338 (1958)

    Google Scholar 

  20. Sen, A.: Collective Choice and Social Welfare (1970)

    Google Scholar 

  21. Shorrocks, A.F.: Decomposition procedures for distributional analysis: a unified framework based on the shapley value. J. Econ. Inequal. 11(1), 99–126 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Son, H.H.: A note on pro-poor growth. Econ. Lett. 82, 307–314 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Stiglitz, J.E.: Pareto efficient and optimal taxation and the new new welfare economics. Handb. Public Econ. 2, 991–1042 (1987)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Sugata Marjit is indebted to the participants of the conference titled “The Economy as a Complex System IV: Can economics be a physical science?” arranged by the Institute of Mathematical Sciences (IMSc). We are also grateful to the seminar participants at IMF, Washington D.C. in July 2017, for helpful comments. We would also like to acknowledge the helpful comments by Sanjeev Gupta of the Fiscal Affairs Department of the IMF. The usual dissimilar applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sugata Marjit .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Mathematical Appendix

Mathematical Appendix

Let \(\{W^i\} :\) endowment vectors \(i=1,2,\ldots ,n;\sum \limits _{i} W^i=W\).

Utility functions, real valued, assumed to be continuous, increasing, strictly quasiconcave : \(\{\bar{U}^i\}\) The consumption possibility set is \(\mathfrak {R}^n_+\) the non-negative orthant. The set of feasible allocation vectors \(\mathfrak {F}=\{\{Y^i\}: Y^i\ge 0, \sum _i Y^i \le W\};~\{W^i\}\in \mathfrak {F}\); \(\mathfrak {U}=\{\{U^i\} : \exists \{Y^i\}\in \mathfrak {F},U^i(Y^i)=\bar{U}^i\forall i\}\) is the set of feasible utilities. Notice \(\{U^i(W^i)\}\in \mathfrak {U}\).

Statement 1 \(\mathfrak {U}\) is a nonempty compact subset of \(\mathfrak {R}^n_{+}\)

Proof: The above follows given the continuity of \(U^i\) over a compact set \(\mathfrak {F}\).

Let \(U^i(W^i)=\hat{U}^i\forall i\); there is a \(P^*=(P^*_1,P^*_2,\ldots ,P^*_n)\) which is a competitive equilibrium i.e., \(X^{i*}\) solves the problem \(max U^i(.)\) subject to \(P^*x\le P^*.W^i \forall i\) and \(\sum _{i}X^{i*}=W\). Let \(U^i(X^{i*}) = U^{i*}\).

Define \(\mathfrak {U}^\mathfrak {P}=\{\{\bar{U}^i\} : \{\bar{U}^i\}\in \mathfrak {U},~\exists \{U^i\}\in \mathfrak {U} ~\text {such that}~,U^i>\bar{U}^i\forall i\}\): Pareto Frontier. The First Fundamental Theorem assures us that \(\{U^{i*}\}\in \mathfrak {U}^\mathfrak {P}\).

Consider next \(\bar{\theta }<\hat{\theta }\); from the property of the supremum, there is \(\tilde{\theta }>\bar{\theta }\) such that \(U(\tilde{\theta })\in \mathfrak {U}\) i.e., there is \(\tilde{Y}^i\) such that \(\{\tilde{Y}\}\in \mathfrak {F}\) and \(U^i(\tilde{Y}^i)=\tilde{\theta }U^i(W^i) \forall i\). Now there must be a scalar \(1>\alpha _i\ge 0\) such that \(U^i(\alpha _i \tilde{Y}^i)=\bar{\theta }.U^i(W^i)\) since by shrinking the scalar \(\alpha _i\) we can make the left hand side go to zero (U is increasing), whereas for \(\alpha _i=1\), the left hand side is greater; also then we can claim \(\{\alpha _i \tilde{Y}^i\}\in \mathfrak {F}\) since

$$\alpha _i \tilde{Y}^i\ge 0$$

and

$$\sum _{i}\alpha _i \tilde{Y}^i\le max_{i} \alpha _i \sum _{i}\tilde{Y}^i \le W$$

\(\quad \square \)

Statement 3 \(U(\hat{\theta })\in \mathfrak {V}\)

Thus one may conclude that \(\{\hat{Y}^i\}\) is a Pareto optimal configuration with the property that \(U^i(\hat{Y}^i)=\hat{\theta }U^i(W^i)\forall i\). And since \(\hat{\theta }\) is uniquely determined, so is the configuration \(\{\hat{Y}^i\}\).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Marjit, S., Mukherji, A., Sarkar, S. (2019). Pareto Efficiency, Inequality and Distribution Neutral Fiscal Policy—An Overview. In: Abergel, F., Chakrabarti, B., Chakraborti, A., Deo, N., Sharma, K. (eds) New Perspectives and Challenges in Econophysics and Sociophysics. New Economic Windows. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-11364-3_13

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics