Skip to main content

Other Topics in Applied Economics

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Vilfredo Pareto: An Intellectual Biography Volume II

Part of the book series: Palgrave Studies in the History of Economic Thought ((PHET))

  • 330 Accesses

Abstract

In the Course in Political Economy and in the writings immediately preceding it, Pareto focused his attention, albeit less extensively, on other topics in applied economics such as the demographic question (Sect. 8.1), questions relating to the science of finance (Sect. 8.2), the functional distribution of national income (Sect. 8.3) and economic crises (Sect. 8.4).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 99.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    On Pareto’s earliest reflections concerning the demographic question, see Mornati (2018, pp. 152–153).

  2. 2.

    Pareto (1893–1894, pp. 35–36), Pareto (1896–1897, §156).

  3. 3.

    Pareto (1893–1894, p. 39), Pareto (1896–1897, §156).

  4. 4.

    Ibid., §§159–162.

  5. 5.

    Ibid., §179.

  6. 6.

    Ibid., §171. On the other hand, Pareto pointed out that it is particularly in the case of human reproduction that “the hedonistic maximum of the individual [can be in contrast] with that of the country or of the species”, §173.

  7. 7.

    Pareto (1893–1894, p. 37).

  8. 8.

    Ibid., p. 37.

  9. 9.

    Ibid., p. 40. Pareto (1896–1897, §217). Pareto considered Malthus’ claim that effective population growth followed an arithmetical progression to be false, and “unsubstantiated” his claim that virtual growth, that is, growth determined by the generating force alone, followed a geometric progression, ibid., §§200, 212.

  10. 10.

    Pareto (1893–1894, pp. 41–42), Pareto (1896–1897, §196). Pareto (1893–1894, p. 47) concluded from this that socialist promises that “with better social organisation mankind could indulge its procreative instincts uninhibitedly” were not credible.

  11. 11.

    Ibid., pp. 64, 66. Pareto, ibid., pp. 80–81 emphasised the futility of government measures to incentivise or to disincentivise births.

  12. 12.

    That is, checks to procreation caused by obstacles or delays to marriage and, after marriage, bans or limits on child-bearing. The former category, unlike the latter, is in any case influenced by variations in economic circumstances, ibid., p. 70, Pareto (1896–1897, §226).

  13. 13.

    Anything provoking premature death in children, in particular infectious diseases (which can often be the result of poverty), Pareto (1893–1894, pp. 76, 79–80).

  14. 14.

    Pareto (1896–1897, §230).

  15. 15.

    Pareto (1893–1894, p. 51). Pareto (1893a, p. 7) having then reiterated that Malthus “was right” in affirming that “the human race, like any other animal species, possesses a natural tendency to breed beyond the limit of subsistence”, denounced Malthus’ opponents for “the injustice … of expecting to measure this phenomenon precisely by reference to the two progressions which have been the subject of so much foolish debate”.

  16. 16.

    Pareto (1896–1897, §222).

  17. 17.

    Ibid., §223.

  18. 18.

    Ibid., §225.

  19. 19.

    Ibid., §268.

  20. 20.

    Pareto to Pantaleoni, 20th May 1896, see Pareto (1984a, p. 449).

  21. 21.

    Pareto to Pantaleoni, 28th October 1896, ibid., p. 478.

  22. 22.

    Pareto (1893b, p. 451).

  23. 23.

    Ibid.

  24. 24.

    Ibid., pp. 451–452.

  25. 25.

    Ibid., pp. 452, 454–455. Pareto pointed out that, out of 100.000 born, 37,806 (25,281) children in Bavaria (Switzerland) die in the first five years of life, while 2382 (3197) die between the ages of 15 and 20, ibid., p. 455 and Pareto (1893–1894, p. 83).

  26. 26.

    Pareto (1893b, p. 456).

  27. 27.

    Pareto (1896–1897, §254).

  28. 28.

    Pareto to Pantaleoni, 21st December 1897, see Pareto (1984b, p. 134).

  29. 29.

    Pareto to Edwin Seligman, 5th January and 1st March 1896, see Pareto (1975, pp. 282, 284). The view had already been expressed in this period in Pareto to Maffeo Pantaleoni, 12th and 14th August 1892, see Pareto (1984a, pp. 266, 268, 272).

  30. 30.

    Pareto to Leon Walras, 28th April 1896, see Pareto (1975, p. 290).

  31. 31.

    Pareto to Edwin Seligman, 1st March 1896, ibid., p. 284.

  32. 32.

    Pareto to Tullio Martello, 15th December 1895, ibid., p. 274.

  33. 33.

    If the rate for progressive taxation were p+[(b(x−x0))/x], where x represents overall income, x0 the minimum income, p the rate applying to the minimum income and b the rate applying to the ratio between the difference between overall income and the minimum income in relation to overall income, it follows that the maximum rate (corresponding to x0 = 0) is p+b, implying that, if p+b<1, the progressive tax “can never absorb either total earnings or increases in earnings”, Pareto to Tullio Martello, 15th December 1895, ibid., p. 275. On the 16th of January 1898 Pareto pointed out to Berthold van Muyden (financial director at the municipality of Lausanne), see Pareto (1989a, pp. 326–327) that, in countries where progressive taxes were implemented, taxpayers’ tax declarations were normally not made public, partly in order not to offer business rivals the opportunity to introduce more effective commercial strategies on the basis of the information gleaned from the tax declarations, and partly in order not to encourage dissembling on the part of taxpayers (such as declaring low sums for fear that to declare greater incomes honestly would make them appear “less shrewd than their fellow-citizens” in their tax dealings).

  34. 34.

    Ibid., p. 328. At the same time, Pareto (1897, p. 233) confirmed that, since (as Cavallotti had also recently observed) “when taxation is excessive, taxpayers defend themselves through fraud”, “in order to obtain a greater return … it would be better to diminish the rates and then ensure that everyone pays exactly what is due (contrary to what the Italian government does)”.

  35. 35.

    Pareto (1894a, pp. 708–709).

  36. 36.

    Pareto (1893c, p. 716). In an address given in Milan on the 20th of December 1892 under the aegis of the Circolo Risorgimento, Pareto specifically denounced the anti-proletarian nature of the extreme tax burden imposed by the Italian state, Il Secolo, 21st–22nd December 1892.

  37. 37.

    Pareto (1893c, p. 717).

  38. 38.

    Ibid.

  39. 39.

    Ibid.

  40. 40.

    Pareto (1893d, pp. 468–469).

  41. 41.

    Pareto (1898, p. 246).

  42. 42.

    Mornati (2018, pp. 141–146).

  43. 43.

    Pareto (1893e, p. 653).

  44. 44.

    Pareto (1896–1897, §473).

  45. 45.

    Pareto (1891a, p. 228).

  46. 46.

    Ibid., pp. 225–226.

  47. 47.

    Ibid., p. 228.

  48. 48.

    Ibid., pp. 229.

  49. 49.

    Pareto (1893–1894, p. 214).

  50. 50.

    Pareto (1896–1897, §747, note 1).

  51. 51.

    Where i represents the interest rate, pT is the price of capital T, … and ∏T is the cost of capital T

  52. 52.

    In fact, for example, 4/3 = 8/6 = (4 + 8)/(3 + 6) = 12/9.

  53. 53.

    Ibid., §§774–775.

  54. 54.

    Ibid., §778.

  55. 55.

    Ibid., §780.

  56. 56.

    Pareto (1892a, p. 558).

  57. 57.

    Ibid., p. 560.

  58. 58.

    Pareto (1895, pp. 477–478).

  59. 59.

    Pareto (1896–1897, §418).

  60. 60.

    Ibid., §419.

  61. 61.

    Ibid., §421.

  62. 62.

    Ibid., §423.

  63. 63.

    Ibid.

  64. 64.

    Pareto (1895, p. 479).

  65. 65.

    Pareto (1896–1897, §438).

  66. 66.

    Ibid., §439.

  67. 67.

    Ibid., §555.

  68. 68.

    Société d’économie politique (Political economy society), Meeting of 5th December 1892, Journal des economistes, LI, XII-3: 464.

  69. 69.

    Pareto (1896–1897, §946).

  70. 70.

    Pareto (1894b, p. 184), Pareto (1896–1897, §949).

  71. 71.

    Ibid., §949.

  72. 72.

    Pareto to Francesco Papafava, 18th August 1890, see Pareto (1980, p. 651).

  73. 73.

    Pareto (1893–1894, p. 181).

  74. 74.

    Pareto (1892b, p. 511).

  75. 75.

    Pareto (1896–1897, §929).

  76. 76.

    Ibid., §930.

  77. 77.

    Ibid., §931.

  78. 78.

    Ibid., §936.

  79. 79.

    Ibid., §937.

  80. 80.

    Ibid.

  81. 81.

    Already in January 1890 Pareto had commented that thanks to Clément Juglar’s “outstanding study” On commercial crises and on their periodic recurrence in France, in England and in the United States (Des crises commerciales et de le leur retour périodique en France, en Angleterre et aux Etats-Unis) it was possible to “track the development of commercial crises very accurately by reference to the balance sheets of the issuing banks”, Pareto to Francesco Papafava, 20th January 1890, see Pareto (1980, p. 646). For a recent publication on Juglar see Bridel and Dal-Pont Legrand, (2009). Pareto (1896–1897, §945) also credited the French statistician Pierre des Essars for having discerned a correspondence between the beginnings (or ends) of crises and the maxima (or minima) of activity on current accounts, by studying the sum totals of annual credits and debits divided by twice the yearly average balance.

  82. 82.

    Pareto (1893–1894, pp. 181–183). As is known, Walter Bagehot, Lombard Street: A Description on Money Market, p. 56 identified in “very large loans at very high rates” the most effective means available to the country holding the nation’s reserves of metal currency to combat the excessive depletion of these reserves occasioned by extraordinary demands for reimbursement on the part of foreign and national depositors. Increases in interest rates will indeed result in inflows of capital from abroad which, by increasing metal reserves, serve to assuage internal fears which are then definitively allayed by the availability of loans, albeit at rates discouraging their utilisation.

  83. 83.

    Pareto (1896–1897, §329).

  84. 84.

    This phenomenon was due, in Pareto’s view, to building speculation and the moving forward of imports prior to the coming into force, on the first of January 1888, of the new higher customs tariff regime, Pareto (1890, p. 392).

  85. 85.

    Ibid.

  86. 86.

    Ibid.

  87. 87.

    On the crisis in the construction and banking sectors of 1889, Confalonieri (1979, pp. 131–159). Pareto (1891b, p. 40), declared that the building crisis “is not finished …, it has not even reached its climax and in many places will get even worse”.

  88. 88.

    Pareto (1890, p. 392).

  89. 89.

    Ibid., p. 394.

  90. 90.

    Pareto (1891c, p. 30).

  91. 91.

    Pareto (1896–1897, §925).

  92. 92.

    Ibid., §926.

  93. 93.

    Ibid.

Bibliography

  • Boianovsky, Mauro. 2001. Economists as demographers: Wicksell and Pareto on population. In Economics and interdisciplinary exchange, ed. G. Erreygers, 117–147. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2013. Before macroeconomics: Pareto and the dynamics of the economics aggregate. Revue européenne des sciences sociales LI-2: 103–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boianovsky, Mauro, and Vincent Tarascio. 1998. Mechanical inertia and economic dynamics: Pareto on business cycles. Journal of History of Economic Thought XX-1: 5–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bridel, Pascal. 2012. Walras and Pareto on the connection between the trade cycle and general equilibrium theory. In Macroeconomics and the history of economic thought: festschrift in honour of Harald Hagemann, ed. H.M. Krämer, H.D. Kurz, and H.M. Trautwein, 78–95. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bridel, Pascal, and Dal-Pont Legrand, Muriel (eds). 2009. Clément Juglar (1819–1905). The origins of the theory of cycles. Revue européenne des sciences sociales, XLVII-143.

    Google Scholar 

  • Confalonieri, Antonio. 1979. Banking and industry in Italy, 1894–1906. I. The prelude: from the abolition of fiat money to the collapse of Credito Mobiliare (Banca e industria in Italia (1894–1906). I. Le premesse: dall’abolizione del corso forzoso alla caduta del Credito Mobiliare). Bologna: Il Mulino.

    Google Scholar 

  • Erreygers, Guido, ed. 2001. Economics and interdisciplinary exchange. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fasiani, Mauro. 1949. Pareto’s contributions to the science of finance (Contributi di Pareto alla Scienza delle Finanze). Giornale degli Economisti e Annali di Economia VIII, 3–4: 129–173.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fossati, Amedeo. 2011. Pareto’s influence on scholar from the Italian tradition in public finance: A critical assessment of Mauro Fasiani’s appraisal. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 3: 466–488.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hagen, Krämer, Heinz D. Kurz, and Hans-Michael Trautwein, eds. 2012. Macroeconomics and the history of economic thought: Festschrift in honour of Harald Hagemann. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • McLure, Michael. 2007. The Paretian School and Italian Fiscal Sociology. Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mornati, Fiorenzo. 2018. Vilfredo Pareto: An intellectual biography. Volume I. From science to liberty (1848–1891). Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pareto, Vilfredo. 1890. Letter from Italy (Lettre d’Italie). Journal des Économistes, IL 6: 387–396.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1891a. Let do, let pass (Lasciate fare, lasciate passare). Giornale degli Economisti II, III-3: 218–234.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———.1891b. Letter from Italy (Lettre d’Italie). Le Monde économique, May 30, p. 526. Reprinted in Pareto (1967, pp. 39–40).

    Google Scholar 

  • ———.1891c. Letter from Italy (Lettre d’Italie). Le Monde économique, April 25, p. 406. Reprinted in Pareto (1967, p. 30).

    Google Scholar 

  • ———.1892a. High wages and low production costs (Alti salari e basso costo di produzione). Il Secolo, December 30–31. Reprinted in Pareto (1989c, pp. 558–561).

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1892b. Considerations on the fundamental principles of pure political economy.II (Considerazioni sui principi fondamentali dell’economia politica pura.II). Giornale degli Economisti III, IV-6: 485–512.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———.1893–1894. [First course in applied political economy, academic year 1893–1894] [Premier cours d’économie appliquée, année académique 1893–1894]. Lausanne: self-publication. Reprinted in Pareto (1982).

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1893a. Considerations on the fundamental principles of pure political economy.IV (Considerazioni sui principi fondamentali dell’economia politica pura.IV). Giornale degli Economisti IV, VI-1: 1–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1893b. Infant mortality and the cost of an adult (La mortalità infantile ed il costo dell’uomo adulto). Giornale degli Economisti IV, VII-5: 451–456.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1893c. The Parliamentary Régime in Italy. Political Science Quarterly VIII, VIII-4: 677–721.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1893d. Report (Cronaca). Giornale degli Economisti IV, VII-5: 463–470.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———.1893e. Competition (Concorrenza). L’Idea liberale, August 20. Reprinted in Pareto (1989c, pp. 653–655).

    Google Scholar 

  • ———.1894a. No tax increases (Nessun aumento di imposte). L’Idea liberale, January 14. Reprinted in Pareto (1989c, pp. 707–710).

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1894b. [Course in applied political economy] ([Cours d’économie politique appliquée]). Lausanne: Self-publication. Reprinted in Pareto (2005, pp. 133–183).

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1895. Mathematical theory of international trade (Teoria matematica del commercio internazionale). Giornale degli Economisti VI, X-4: 476–498.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———.1896–1897. Course in political economy (Cours d’économie politique). Lausanne: Rouge.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———.1897. Financial public statement (L’esposizione finanziaria). Il Secolo, December 13–14. Reprinted in Pareto (1989b, pp. 232–235).

    Google Scholar 

  • ———.1898. Military expenditure (Spese militari). Il Secolo, January 2–3. Reprinted in Pareto (1989b, pp. 243–246).

    Google Scholar 

  • ———.1967. Letters from Italy (Lettres d’Italie), Complete works, tome X, ed. Giovanni Busino. Geneva: Droz.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———.1975. Correspondence, 1890–1923 (Epistolario 1890–1923), Complete works, tome XIX-1, ed. Giovanni Busino. Geneva: Droz.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———.1980. Letters 1860–1860 (Lettres 1860–1890), Complete works, tome XXIII, ed. Giovanni Busino. Geneva: Droz.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———.1982. [First course in applied political economy, academic year 1893–1894] [Premier cours d’économie appliquée, année académique 1893–1894], Complete works, tome XXIV, ed. Giovanni Busino. Geneva: Droz.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———.1984a. Letters to Maffeo Pantaleoni 1890–1896 (Lettere a Maffeo Pantaleoni 1890–1896), Complete works, tome XXVIII.I, ed. Gabriele De Rosa. Geneva: Droz.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———.1984b. Letters to Maffeo Pantaleoni 1897–1906 (Lettere a Maffeo Pantaleoni 1897–1906), Complete works, tome XXVIII.II, ed. Gabriele De Rosa. Geneva: Droz.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———.1989a. Letters and Correspondence (Lettres et Correspondances), Complete works, tome XXX, ed. Giovanni Busino. Geneva: Droz.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———.1989b. Political writings. Reaction, liberty and fascism (Scritti politici. Reazione, libertà, fascismo), Complete works, tome XVIII. ed. Giovanni Busino. Geneva: Droz.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———.1989c. Political writings. The development of capitalism (Scritti politici. Lo sviluppo del capitalismo), Complete works, tome XVII. ed. Giovanni Busino. Geneva: Droz.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2005. Unpublished works and Addenda (Inédits et Addenda), Complete works, tome XXXII, ed. Fiorenzo Mornati. Geneva: Droz.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spengler, Joseph J. 1944. Pareto on Population. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, LVIII-4: 571–601; LIX: 107–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Fiorenzo Mornati .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Mornati, F. (2018). Other Topics in Applied Economics. In: Vilfredo Pareto: An Intellectual Biography Volume II. Palgrave Studies in the History of Economic Thought. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-04540-1_8

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-04540-1_8

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-04539-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-04540-1

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics