Skip to main content

Wealth Creation in Primitive Economies

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Economic Wealth Creation and the Social Division of Labour
  • 379 Accesses

Abstract

In this chapter we consider two models of primitive economies made up of consumer-producers. Under autarky, consumer-producers in a state of self-sufficiency optimises their production to satisfy their own consumptive needs. This represents a situation similar to the position of peasants in an agricultural economy. Next, we look at economies in which autarkic consumer-producers have limited interactions to form a sparse trade infrastructure. These autarkic consumer-producers are assumed to interact through binary trade relationships only, forming trade infrastructures as network configurations of such binary trade relationships. We show that in these environments trade naturally leads to individually rational and socially optimal reallocations of the generated wealth, but there does not emerge a “general” equilibrium.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The reproduction of labour force and the farm’s capacity refers here to the required farm products to sustain the life of a peasant family over the year. This corresponds to the output level of the farm in terms of required inputs and outputs to break even. A surplus refers to the case where the farm produces outputs beyond the reproduction level required.

  2. 2.

    This refers to the standard Lagrange method in calculus to compute an optimum of a function under a constraint. For an elaborate discussion of this method and its applications, I refer to Trench (2013) and Sydseater et al. (2016).

  3. 3.

    Here we point out that the Stone–Geary utility function indicates that neither food nor shelter are necessities for survival. Thus, x′ = 0 does not indicate starvation, but a minimal level of food gathering for bare survival.

  4. 4.

    This form of exhaustion of gains from exchange through barter negotiations is also known as Edgeworthian barter, named for Francis Edgeworth (1845–1926) who first developed this form of trade in his groundbreaking contribution to economics in Edgeworth (1881).

  5. 5.

    We note here that barter and trade are engaged in complete freedom and are not coerced in any way. Individual rationality is a representation of this freedom to engage or not.

  6. 6.

    For more detailed discussion of the various forms of Pareto optimality, see Kreps (2013).

  7. 7.

    Historically, Edgeworth (1881) introduced a two-axes version of this representation, without representing these barter relationships as a rectangular box. Subsequently, the modern usage as a proper box was developed in Pareto (1906) and Bowley (1924).

  8. 8.

    This can be verified from standard textbooks on neo-classical microeconomic theory such as Jehle and Reny (2000) and Kreps (2013).

  9. 9.

    The exchange rate r as defined here is an exact representation of the “labour value” of Y in terms of good X. I refer to the discussion in Chap. 4 of the labour theory of value for an elaborate justification of this interpretation.

  10. 10.

    The notion of an economic rent here indicates a profit or return that goes beyond the economic notion of an opportunity cost. Thus, an economic rent refers to a positive return on an investment. In this case, a positional rent is a return on one’s position in the prevailing infrastructure in the economy or socio-economic space.

  11. 11.

    Foley refers to the equilibrium defined in Definition 2.14 as an exchange equilibrium to delineate it from the standard competitive Arrow–Debreu equilibrium (Arrow and Debreu 1954).

  12. 12.

    Even today we perform a lot of economic value-generating tasks inside the home, which can be classified as autarkic activities.

  13. 13.

    One of the richest individuals in history was Marcus Crassus (115–53 BCE), who had personal wealth equal to that of the Roman treasury. Crassus ran a personal business empire based on slave trade, exploitation of silver mines, and real estate speculation.

  14. 14.

    This term refers to the type of economy seminally described by Plato (380 BCE) for the Greek polis. These economies were centred around well-developed horizontal divisions of labour based on artisan professionals, supported by a rural base of productive farming communities.

  15. 15.

    Theoretically, in the feudal hierarchical order the local landlord was assumed to protect the villages against such marauders. However, that was usually not the case and in many situations the local landlord might even take part in the pillaging.

  16. 16.

    Peasants were also marginally differentiated through the home production of consumables. One peasant might be good at producing pottery, another at building barns. But these activities remained marginal in comparison with the agricultural production that took place in the village economy.

References

  • Arrow, K.J., and G. Debreu. 1954. Existence of Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy. Econometrica 22: 265–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowley, A.L. 1924. The Mathematical Groundwork of Economics: An Introductory Treatise. London: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chapelot, J., and R. Fossier. 1985. The Village & House in the Middle Ages. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, G. 2007. A Farewell to Alms: A Brief Economic History of the World. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cunliffe, B. 2003. The Celts: A Very Short Introduction. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Debreu, G. 1959. Theory of Value. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edgeworth, F.Y. 1881. Mathematical Psychics: An Essay on the Application of Mathematics to the Moral Sciences. London: C. Kegan Paul & Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fleming, R. 2010. Britain After Rome: The Fall and Rise, 400 - 1070. London: Allen Lane (Penguin).

    Google Scholar 

  • Foley, D.K. 2010. What’s Wrong with the Fundamental Existence and Welfare Theorems? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 75: 115–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilles, R.P. 2018. Economic Wealth Creation and the Social Division of Labour: I - Institutions and Trust. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Jehle, G.A., and P.J. Reny. 2000. Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Boston: Addison Wesley Longman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kreps, D.M. 2013. Microeconomic Foundations I: Choice and Competitive Markets. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Malthus, T.R. 1798. An Essay on the Principle of Population, as It Affects the Future Improvement of Society. London: J. Johnson, St. Paul’s Church Yard.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCormick, M. 2001. Origins of the European Economy: Communications and Commerce AD 300–900. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pareto, V. 1906. Manual of Political Economy. 1972 reprint ed. London: Macmillan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Plato. 380 BCE. Republic. 2007 ed. London: Penguin Classics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Postan, M.M. 1972. The Medieval Economy and Society. London: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubinstein, A., and A. Wolinsky. 1987. Middlemen. Quarterly Journal of Economics 102: 581–593.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • _________. 1990. Decentralised Trading, Strategic Behaviour and the Walrasian Outcome. Review of Economic Studies 57: 63–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sydseater, K., P. Hammond, A. Strom, and A. Carvajal. 2016. Essential Mathematics for Economic Analysis. 5th ed. London: Pearson Education Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Temin, P. 2006. The Economy of the Early Roman Empire. Journal of Economic Perspectives 20 (1): 133–151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • _________. 2012. The Roman Market Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Townsend, R.M. 1993. The Medieval Village Economy: A Study of the Pareto Mapping in General Equilibrium Models. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trench, W.F. 2013. The Method of Lagrange Multipliers: Supplement to Introduction to Real Analysis. Open Source. https://works.bepress.com/william_trench/130/.

  • Verhulst, A. 2002. The Carolingian Economy. Cambridge Medieval Textbooks. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Wickham, C. 2009. The Inheritance of Rome: A History of Europe from 400 to 1000. London: Allen Lane (Penguin).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Robert P. Gilles .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Gilles, R.P. (2019). Wealth Creation in Primitive Economies. In: Economic Wealth Creation and the Social Division of Labour. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-04426-8_2

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-04426-8_2

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-04425-1

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-04426-8

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics