Advertisement

Rationality and the Green Revolution

  • Bram TuckerEmail author
Chapter
Part of the Advances in the Evolutionary Analysis of Human Behaviour book series (AEAHB, volume 1)

Abstract

Adaptation via differential success among competing individuals creates winners and losers. But adaptation via cultural group selection creates benefits that are shared among group members. During the twentieth century, evolutionary biologists and economists developed parallel theories of rationality, the gene’s eye view and rational choice theory, which imagine humans as self-interested individuals maximizing consumption of scarce resources. When rational choice theory was applied to agricultural development in the Green Revolution programs of the 1940s to the 1980s, it turned otherwise cooperative farmers into competitors for cash profits, resulting in a process akin to differential mortality, generating wealth for some but exacerbating poverty for many. I suggest that evolutionary biology may offer an alternative view of human rationality, one consistent with ethnographic evidence of farmers’ behavior. One emerging candidate for a “Rationality 2.0” assumes cultural inheritance, cultural group selection, strong reciprocity, and bounded rationality. Farmers make decisions that balance individual benefits with family and community well-being. While the new Alliance for a Green Revolution for Africa (AGRA) seeks technical solutions within its seeds, soils, policy, and markets programs, Rationality 2.0 suggests that AGRA should also promote community cohesion, autonomy, human capability, and reduced dependence on imported technology.

Keywords

Rationality Sociality Green revolution Agriculture International development Strong reciprocity Cultural group selection 

Notes

Acknowledgments

Many of the ideas expressed here were developed while a fellow at the Wissenschaftskolleg zu Berlin, particularly during discussions with Monique Borgerhoff Mulder, Alex Courtiol, Jim Hunt, Phillip Kitcher, and Virpi Lummaa. I appreciate insightful comments on a previous draft supplied by Shakti Lamba, Mhairi Gibson, David Lawson, Susannah Chapman, Jessica Ham, Laura Tilghman, and an anonymous reviewer. Thanks to J. Stephen Lansing and Joseph Lanning for permission to use their photographs.

References

  1. AGRA. (2008). AGRA in 2008: Building on the new momentum in African agriculture. Nairobi: Alliance for a Green Revolution in Africa.Google Scholar
  2. AGRA. (2009). AGRA in 2009: Engaging globally, working locally. Nairobi: Alliance for a Green Revolution in Africa.Google Scholar
  3. AGRA. (2010). AGRA in 2010: Driving real change. Nairobi: Alliance for a Green Revolution in Africa.Google Scholar
  4. AGRA. (2011). AGRA in 2011: Investing in sustainable growth. Nairobi: Alliance for a Green Revolution in Africa.Google Scholar
  5. Allais, M. (1953). Le comportement de l’homme rationnel devant le risque: Critique des postulats et axiomes de l’école américaine. Econometrica, 21(4), 503–546.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Antle, J. M., & Pingali, P. L. (1994). Pesticides, productivity, and farmer health: A philippine case study. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 76, 418–430.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Atran, S., & Henrich, J. (2010). The evolution of religion: How cognitive by-products, adaptive learning heuristics, ritual displays, and group competition generate deep commitments to prosocial religions. Biological Theory, 5(1), 18–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Axelrod, R., & Hamilton, W. D. (1981). The evolution of cooperation. Science, 211(4489), 1390–1396.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Beattie, J. H. M. (1964). Kinship and social anthropology. Man, 64, 101–103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Binmore, K. (2005). Economic man—or straw man? Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 28(6), 817–818.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Binswanger, H. P. (2007). Empowering people for their own development. Agricultural Economics, 37, 13–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Blaug, M. (1962). Economic theory in retrospect. Homewood Hills, Il.: R.D. Irwin.Google Scholar
  13. Blaustein, R. J. (2008). The Green Revolution arrives in Africa. BioScience, 58(1), 8–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Bohannan, P., & Middleton, J. (1968). Kinship and social organizaton. Garden City: The American Museum of Natural History.Google Scholar
  15. Boyd, R., & Richerson, P. J. (1988). An evolutionary model of social learning: The effects of spatial and temporal variation. In T. R. Zentall & G. Galef. Bennett (Eds.), Social learning: Psychological and biological perspectives (pp. 29–48). Hillsdale: Lawrence Elbaum Associates.Google Scholar
  16. Boyd, R., & Richerson, P. J. (1992). Punishment allows the evolution of cooperation (or anything else) in sizable groups. Ethology and Sociobiology, 13(3), 171–195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Boyd, R., & Richerson, P. J. (2010). Transmission coupling mechanisms: Cultural group selection. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B, 365, 3787–3795.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Boyd, R., Richerson, P. J., & Henrich, J. (2011). Rapid cultural adaptation can facilitate the evolution of large-scale cooperation. Behavioral Ecology and Sociobiology, 65, 431–444.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Broome, J. (1991). Utility. Economics and Philosophy, 7, 1–12.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Brush, S. B. (1992). Reconsidering the Green Revolution: Diversity and stability in cradle areas of crop domestication. Human Ecology, 20(2), 145–167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Cancian, F. (1989). Economic behavior in peasant communities. In S. Plattner (ed.), Economic Anthropology (pp. 127-170). Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
  22. Chibnik, M. (1994). Risky Rivers: The economics and politics of floodplain farming in Amazonia. Tucson: University of Alabama Press.Google Scholar
  23. Clawson, D. L., & Hoy, D. R. (1979). Nealtican, Mexico: A peasant community that rejected the ’Green Revolution’. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 38(4), 371–387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Cleaver, H. M. (1972). The contradictions of the green revolution. The American Economic Review, 62, 177–186.Google Scholar
  25. Dawkins, R. (1976). The selfish gene. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  26. de Gregori, T. R. (2004). Green revolution myth and agricultural reality? Journal of Economic Issues, 38(2), 503–508.Google Scholar
  27. de Munck, V. (2000). Culture, self, and meaning. Prospect Heights: Waveland Press, Inc.Google Scholar
  28. de Janvry, A., Fafchamps, M., & Sadoulet, E. (1991). Peasant household behavior with missing markets: Some paradoxes explained. Economic Journal, 101(409), 1400–1417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Ellis, F. (1988). Peasant economics: Farm households and agrarian development. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  30. Elster, J. (1982). Marxism, functionalism, and game theory: The case for methodological individualism. Theory and Society, 11, 453–482.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Elster, J. (1986). Introduction. In J. Elster (Ed.), Rational choice (pp. 1–33). New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
  32. Evans-Pritchard, E. E. (1937). Witchcraft, oracles, and magic among the Azande. Oxford: The Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
  33. Evenson, R. E., & Gollin, D. (2003). Assessing the impact of the Green Revolution, 1960 to 2000. Science, 300(5620), 758–762.Google Scholar
  34. FAO. (2009). How to feed the world in 2050: Global agriculture towards 2050. Rome: Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations.Google Scholar
  35. Foley, R. (1985). Optimality theory in anthropology. Man, 20(2), 222–241.Google Scholar
  36. Fortes, M. (1953). The structure of unilineal descent groups. American Anthropologist, 55(1), 17–41.Google Scholar
  37. Foster, G. M. (1965). Peasant society and the image of limited good. American Anthropologist, 67(2), 293–315.Google Scholar
  38. Frankena, W. K. (1939). The naturalistic fallacy. Mind, 48(192), 464–477.Google Scholar
  39. Freebairn, D. K. (1995). Did the green revolution concentrate incomes? A quantitative study of research reports. World Development, 23(2), 265–279.Google Scholar
  40. Gerkey, D. (2013). Cooperation in context: Public goods games and post-Soviet collectives in Kamchatka, Russia. Current Anthropology, 54(2), 144–176.Google Scholar
  41. Gigerenzer, G., Todd, P. M., & ABC Research. (2000). Simple heuristics that make us smart. Oxford: Oxford University Press Group.Google Scholar
  42. Gintis, H. (2000). Strong reciprocity and human sociality. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 206, 169–179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Gurven, M., & Winking, J. (2008). Collective action in action: Prosocial behavior in and out of the laboratory. American Anthropologist, 110(2), 179–190.Google Scholar
  44. Hagen, E. H., & Hammerstein, P. (2006). Game theory and evolution: A critique of some recent interpretations of economic games. Theoretical Population Biology, 69, 339–348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Hamilton, W. D. (1964). The genetical evolution of social behavior. I. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 7, 1–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of commons. Science, 162(3859), 1243–1248.Google Scholar
  47. Harlan, J. R. (1975). Our vanishing genetic resources. Science, 188, 618–621.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Hawkes, K., & Bird, R. B. (2002). Showing off, handicap signaling, and the evolution of men’s work. Evolutionary Anthropology, 11(2), 58–67.Google Scholar
  49. Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., Gintis, H., et al. (2005). Economic man in cross-cultural perspective: Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 28(6), 795–855.Google Scholar
  50. Herrmann, B., Thöni, C., & Gächter, S. (2008). Antisocial punishment across societies. Science, 319, 1362–1367.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Horner, V., & Whiten, A. (2005). Causal knowledge and imitation/emulation switching in chimpanzees and children. Animal Cognition, 8, 164–181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Hunt, E. K. (2002). History of economic thought. Armonk: M. E. Sharpe.Google Scholar
  53. Hutchinson, J. M. C., & Gigerenzer, G. (2005). Simple heuristics and rules of thumb: Where psychologists and behavioral ecologists might meet. Behavioural Processes, 69, 97–124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Jones, B. G. (2005). Africa and the poverty of international relations. Third World Quarterly, 26(6), 987–1003.Google Scholar
  55. Junankar, P. N. (1975). Green revolution and inequality. Economic and Political Weekly, 10(13), A15–A18.Google Scholar
  56. Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (2000). Choices, values, and frames. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  57. Klemick, H., & Lichtenberg, E. (2008). Pesticide use and fish harvests in Vietnamese rice agroecosystems. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 90(1), 1–14.Google Scholar
  58. Knutson, B., & Peterson, R. (2005). Neurally reconstructing expected utility. Games and Economic Behavior, 52, 305–315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Laland, K. N., & Brown, G. R. (2002). Sense and nonsense: Evolutionary perspectives on human behaviour. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  60. Lansing, J. S. (1991). Priests and programmers. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  61. Lee, R. B. (1990). Primitive communism and the origin of social inequality. In S. Upham (Ed.), The evolution of political systems (pp. 225-246). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  62. Lee, R. B. (2003). The Dobe Ju/’hoansi. Belmont: Wadsworth Thomson Learning.Google Scholar
  63. Lehmann, L., Feldman, M. W., & Foster, K. (2008). Cultural transmission can inhibit the evolution of altruistic helping. American Naturalist, 172, 12–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. Luce, D. R., & Raiffa, H. (1957). Games and decisions: Introduction and critical survey. New York: Dover Publications Inc.Google Scholar
  65. Lyle, H. F., & Smith, E. A. (2012). How conservative are evolutionary anthropologists? A survey of political attitudes. Human Nature, 23, 306–322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  66. Malthus, T. R. (1888). An Essay on the Principle of Population. London: Reeves and Turner.Google Scholar
  67. Marlowe, F. W., Berbesque, J. C., Barr, A., Barrett, C., Bolyanatz, A., Cardenas, J. C., et al. (2008). More ’altrusitic’ punishment in larger societies. Proceedings of the Royal Society B, 275, 587–590.Google Scholar
  68. Mauss, M.. (1967). [1925]. The gift: Forms and functions of exchange in archaic societies. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
  69. McElreath, R., Boyd, R., & Richerson, P. J. (2003). Shared norms and the evolution of ethnic markers. Current Anthropology, 44(1), 122–129.Google Scholar
  70. Meza-Montenegro, M. M., Gandolfi, A. J., Santana-Alcantar, M. E., Klimecki. Walter T., Aguilar-Apodaca, M. G., del Rio-Salas, R., et al (2012). Metals in residential soils and cumulative risk assessment in Yaqui and Mayo agricultural valleys, northern Mexico. Science of the Total Environment, 433, 472–481.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  71. Murgai, R., Ali, M., & Byerlee, D. (2001). Productivity growth and sustainability in post-Green Revolution agriculture: The case of the Indian and Pakistan Punjabs. The World Bank Research Observer, 16(2), 199–218.Google Scholar
  72. Nanda, M. (1995). Transnationalisation of Third World State and undoing of green revolution. Economic and Political Weekly, 30(2), PE20–PE30.Google Scholar
  73. Netting, R. McC. (1981). Balancing on an Alp: Ecological change and continuity in a Swiss mountain community. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  74. Netting, R. McC. (1993). Smallholders, householders: Farm families and the ecology of intensive, sustainable agriculture. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
  75. Padoa-Schioppa, C., & Assad, J. A. (2006). Neurons in the orbitofrontal cortex encode economic value. Nature, 441, 223–226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  76. Polanyi, K. (1977). The livelihood of man. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
  77. Prahladachar, M. (1983). Income distribution effects of the Green Revolution in India: A review of empirical evidence. World Development, 11(11), 927–944.Google Scholar
  78. Price, G. R. (1970). Selection and covariance. Nature, 277, 520–521.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  79. Price, G. R. (1972). Extensions of covariance selection mathematics. Annals of Human Genetics, 35, 485–490.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  80. Richerson, P. J., & Boyd, R. (2005). Not by genes alone: How culture transformed human evolution. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  81. Rogers, E. M. (2003). Diffusion of innovations. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
  82. Ross, N. (2004). Cognition and culture: Implications for theory and method. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications Inc.Google Scholar
  83. Ryan, B., & Gross, N. C. (1943). The diffusion of hybrid corn in two Iowa communities. Rural Sociology, 8, 15–24.Google Scholar
  84. Sachs, J. D., McArthur, J. W., Schmidt-Traub, G., Kruk, M., Bahadur, C., Faye, M., et al. (2004). Ending Africa’s poverty trap. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2004(1), 117–216.Google Scholar
  85. Sahlins, M. (1972). Stone age economics. New York: Aldine de Gruyter.Google Scholar
  86. Sahlins, M. (1976). The use and abuse of biology: An anthropological critique of sociobiology. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
  87. Sen, A. (1983). Poor, relatively speaking. Oxford Economic Papers, 35(2), 153–169.Google Scholar
  88. Sen, A. (2000). Development as freedom. New York: Anchor.Google Scholar
  89. Scott, J. C. (1976). The moral economy of the peasant: Rebellion and subsistence in Southeast Asia. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  90. Shipton, P. (1989). Bitter money: Cultural economy and some African meanings of forbidden commodities. Washington, D.C: American Anthropological Association.Google Scholar
  91. Simon, H. A. (1957). Models of man, social and rational: Mathematical essays on rational behavior in a social setting. New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc.Google Scholar
  92. Singh, I., & Day, R. H. (1975). A microeconometric chronicle of the Green Revolution. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 23(4), 661–686.Google Scholar
  93. Smith, E. A. (2005). Making it real: Interpreting economic experiments. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 28(6), 832–833.Google Scholar
  94. Smith, E. A., & Winterhalder, B. (1992). Natural selection and decision-making: Some fundamental principles. In: E. A. Smith & B. Winterhalder (Eds.), Evolution and human behavior (pp. 25–60). New York: Aldine de Gruyter.Google Scholar
  95. Sperber, D., & Claidiere, N. (2008). Defining and explaining culture (comments on Richerson and Boyd, Not by genes alone). Biology and Philosophy, 23, 283–292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  96. Stephens, D. W. (1981). The logic of risk-sensitive foraging preferences. Animal Behaviour, 29(2), 628–629.Google Scholar
  97. Stephens, D. W., & Krebs, J. R. (1986). Foraging theory. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  98. Stone, G. D. (2007). Agricultural deskilling and the spread of genetically modified cotton in Warangal. Current Anthropology, 48(1), 67–103.Google Scholar
  99. Trivers, R. L. (1971). Evolution of reciprocal altruism. Quarterly Review of Biology, 46(1), 35–57.Google Scholar
  100. Tucker, B., Huff, A., Tsiazonera, Tombo, J., Hajasoa, P., & Nagnisaha, C. (2011). When the wealthy are poor: Poverty explanations and local perspectives in southwestern Madagascar. American Anthropologist, 113(2), 291–305.Google Scholar
  101. Tucker, B. (2012). Do risk and time experimental choices represent individual strategies for coping with poverty or conformity to social norms? Evidence from rural southwestern Madagascar. Current Anthropology, 53(2), 149–180.Google Scholar
  102. Tybur, J. M., Miller, G. F., & Gangestad, S. W. (2007). Testing the controversy: An empirical examination of adaptationists’ attitudes towards politics and science. Human Nature, 18, 323–328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  103. Von Neumann, J., & Morgenstern, O. (1944). Theory of games and economic behavior. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  104. Wade, N. (1974). Green Revolution I: A just technology, often unjust in use. Science, 186(4169), 1093–1096.Google Scholar
  105. West, S. A., Griffin, A. S., & Gardner, A. (2008). Social semantics: How useful has group selection been? Journal of Evolutionary Biology, 21, 374–385.Google Scholar
  106. West, S. A., Mouden, C. E., & Gardner, A. (2011). Sixteen common misconceptions about the evolution of cooperation in humans. Evolution and Human Behavior, 32, 231–262.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  107. Wiessner, P. (2009). Experimental games and games of life among the Ju/’hoan Bushmen. Current Anthropology, 50(1), 133–138.Google Scholar
  108. Williams, G. C. (1966). Adaptation and natural selection. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  109. Wilson, D. S., & Wilson, E. O. (2007). Rethinking the theoretical foundations of sociobiology. The Quarterly Review of Biology, 82(4), 327–348.Google Scholar
  110. Wolf, E. R. (1957). Closed corporate peasant communities in Mesoamerica and central Java. Southwestern Journal of Anthropology, 13(1), 1–18.Google Scholar
  111. Woolcock, M. (1998). Social capital and economic development: Toward a theoretical synthesis and policy framework. Theory and Society, 27, 151–208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  112. Wynne-Edwards, V. C. (1962). Animal dispersion in relation to social behaviour. Edinburgh: Oliver and Boyd.Google Scholar
  113. Yapa, L. (1993). What are improved seeds? An epistemology of the green revolution. Economic Geography, 69(3), 254–273.Google Scholar
  114. Zentall, T. R., & Galef, B. G. (1988). Social learning: Psychological and biological perspectives. Hillsdale: Lawrence Erlba.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2014

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of AnthropologyUniversity of GeorgiaAthensUSA

Personalised recommendations