Advertisement

Empirical Evidence on Common Money and Uncommon Regions in the United States

  • Michael Horvath
Part of the ZEI Studies in European Economics and Law book series (ZEIS, volume 1)

Abstract

European monetary unification by eleven member states in January 1999 will create a currency union. The road to monetary union over the past decade or more has not been a smooth one. A particular concern among economists and politicians alike is the extent to which the adoption and use of a common currency prevents members in the currency union from engaging in region-specific monetary and fiscal policies in response to region-specific disturbances. The notion of optimality in a currency area, as propounded by Mundell (1961), Meade (1957), and Kenen (1969) made explicit reference to the geographic nature of shocks. Regions whose various economic shocks were highly correlated would not suffer from the loss of autonomy in monetary policy implied by currency unification since monetary responses to economic disturbances that were optimal for the union as a whole should be optimal for all regions of the union individually.

Keywords

Monetary Policy European Monetary Union Currency Union Taylor Rule Census Region 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Bayoumi, Tamim and Barry Eichengreen. (1992) “Shocking Aspects of European Monetary Integration”, in F. Torres and F. Giavazzi (eds.) Adjustment and Growth in the European Monetary Union. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  2. Barro, Robert J. and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. (1991) “Convergence across States and Regions,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity.Google Scholar
  3. Bemanke, Benjamin and Ilian Mihov. (1995) “Measuring Monetary Policy”, National Bureau of Economic Research, WP 5145.Google Scholar
  4. Blanchard, Olivier and Lawrence F. Katz. (1992) “Regional Evolutions,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 1, 1–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Carlin, Gerald and Robert DeFina. (1997) “The Differential Regional Effects of Monetary Policy,” manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.Google Scholar
  6. Cohen, Daniel and Charles Wyplosz. (1989) “The European Monetary Union: An Agnostic Evaluation,” Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper No. 306, London.Google Scholar
  7. Davis, Steven J. and John Haltiwanger. (1997) “Sectoral Job Creation and Destruction Responses to Oil Price Changes and Other Shocks,” manuscript, University of Maryland and Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago.Google Scholar
  8. Davis, Steven J., John Haltiwanger and Scott Schuh. (1996) Job Creation and Destruction. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  9. Davis, Steven J., Prakash Loungani, and Ramamohan Mahidhara. (1997) “Regional Labor Fluctuations: Oil Shocks, Military Spending, and other Driving Forces,” manuscript, Federal Reserve Board of Governors.Google Scholar
  10. Delors Report (Committee for the Study of Economic and Monetary Union) (1989) Report on Economic and Monetary Union in the European Community, Office for Official Publications of the EC, Luxembourg.Google Scholar
  11. Eichengreen, Barry (1990) “One Money for Europe? Lessons from the US Currency and Customs Union”, Economic Policy, 10, 118–87.Google Scholar
  12. Evans, Charles L. and David A. Marshall. (1997) “Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Nominal Interest Rates: Evidence and Theory,” manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.Google Scholar
  13. Goldstein, Morris and Geoffrey Woglom. (1992) “Market-Based Fiscal Discipline in Monetary Unions: Evidence from the US Municipal Bond Market,” in M. Canzoneri, V. Grilli, and P. Masson (eds.) Establishing a Central Bank: Issues in Europe and Lessons from the US. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  14. Hall, Robert E. (1997) “The Amplification and Persistence of Employment Fluctations Through Labor Market Frictions,” forthcoming in J. Taylor and M. Woodford (eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics.Google Scholar
  15. Hamilton, James D. (1988) “A Neoclassical Model of Unemployment and the Business Cycle,” Journal of Political Economy, 96, 593–617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Hamilton, James D. (1996) “This is What Happened to the Oil Price-Macroeconomy Relationship,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 38, 215–222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Hooker, Mark. (1996) “What Happened to the Oil Price-Macroeconomy Relationship?,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 38, 195–213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Hooker, Mark and Michael M. Knetter. (1996) “The Effects of Military Spending on Economic Activity: Evidence from State Procurement Spending,” manuscript, Dartmouth College.Google Scholar
  19. Horvath, Michael. (1998) “Cyclicality and Sectoral Linkages: Aggregate Fluctuations from Independent Sectoral Shocks,” Review of Economic Dynamics, 1, 781–808.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Horvath, Michael. (1999) “Sectoral Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations,” (forthcoming) Journal of Monetary Economics.Google Scholar
  21. Horvath, Michael and Randal J. Verbrugge. (1997) “Shocks and Sectoral Interactions: An Empirical Investigation,” manuscript, Stanford University.Google Scholar
  22. Kenen, Peter B. (1969) “The Theory of Optimum Currency Areas: An Eclectic View,” in Robert A. Mundell and A.K. Swoboda, eds., Monetary Problems in the International Economy, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  23. Kilian, Lutz. (1998) “Small-Sample Confidence Intervals for Impulse Response Functions,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 80, 218–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Kletzer, Kenneth M. (1997) “Macroeconomic Stabilization with a Common Currency: Does European Monetary Unification Create a Need For Fiscal Insurance or Federalism?”, manuscript, Zentrum für Europäische Integrationsforshung, ZEI Policy Paper B97–04.Google Scholar
  25. Meade (1957).Google Scholar
  26. Mundell, Robert A. (1961) “A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas,” American Economic Review, 51, 657–675.Google Scholar
  27. Sala-i-Martin, Xavier and Jeffrey Sachs. (1992) “Fiscal Federalism and Optimum Currency Areas: Evidence for Europe from the United States,” in M. Canzoneri, V. Grilli, and P. Masson (eds.) Establishing a Central Bank: Issues in Europe and Lessons from the US. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  28. Sims, Christopher. (1982) “ Policy Analysis with Econometric Models,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 107–52.Google Scholar
  29. Sims, Christopher and Tao Zha. (1994) “Error Bands for Impulse Responses,” Yale University, Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper: 1085.Google Scholar
  30. Taylor, John B. (1993) “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 39, 195–214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. von Hagen, Jürgen. (1992) “Fiscal Arrangements in a Monetary Union: Evidence from the US”, in D. E. Fair and C. de Boissieu (eds.) Fiscal Policy, Taxation and the Financial System in an Increasingly Integrated Europe. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.Google Scholar
  32. von Hagen, Jürgen. (1998) “Budgeting Institutions for Aggregate Fiscal Discipline,” manuscript, Zentrum für Europäische Integrationsforshung, ZEI Policy Paper B98–0I.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2000

Authors and Affiliations

  • Michael Horvath
    • 1
  1. 1.Stanford UniversityStanfordUSA

Personalised recommendations