The Efficiency of Organizational Forms

  • Donald W. Katzner

Abstract

For a long time economists have been aware of the fact that certain ways of organizing firms are more efficient than others. Adam Smith, for example, knew that a firm producing pins in which employees specialized in straightening wire, cutting wire, making points, etc. would be more efficient than one in which each worker produced complete pins by himself alone.2 However, recent approaches to this problem (e.g., Beckmann [1], Calvo and Wellisz [2], Sah and Stiglitz [12], and Willamson [14], [15]) have tended to de-emphasize the technological aspects of production and centered instead on certain social relations among individuals in the firm. These social relations arise in that some workers are “above” other workers in the firm’s authority structure; they are significant because it is the social interactions between those above and those below which seem to be responsible for coordinating effort and seeing production through.

Keywords

Income Expense Pyramid Librium Rium 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. 1.
    Beckmann, M. J., Rank in Organizations (Berlin: Springer-Verlag, 1978).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. 2.
    Calvo, G. A., and S. Wellisz, “Hierarchy, Ability and Income Distribution,” Journal of Political Economy 87(1979), pp. 991–1010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. 3.
    Coase, R. H., “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica, n.s. 4 (1937), pp. 386–405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. 4.
    Gintis, H., and D. W. Katzner, “Profits, Optimality and the Social Division of Labor in the Firm,” in Sociological Economics, L. Lévy-Garboua, ed. (London: SAGE, 1979), pp. 269–297. Reprinted as Ch. 11 in D. W. Katzner, Analysis without Measurement (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983).Google Scholar
  5. 5.
    Janowitz, M., Sociology and the Military Establishment, rev. ed. (New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 1965).Google Scholar
  6. 6.
    Katzner, D. W., Analysis without Measurement (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. 7.
    Katzner, D. W., “The Role of Formalism in Economic Thought, with Illustration Drawn from the Analysis of Social Interaction in the Firm,” in The Reconstruction of Economic Theory, P. Mirowski, ed. (Boston: KIuwer-Nijhoff, 1986), pp. 137–177. This volume, Essay 6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. 8.
    Lang, K., “Military Organizations,” in Handbook of Organizations, J. C. March, ed. (Chicago: Rand McNally, 1965), Ch. 20.Google Scholar
  9. 9.
    Leibenstein, H., Beyond Economic Man (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1976).Google Scholar
  10. 10.
    Ouchi, W. G., “Markets, Bureaucracies, and Clans,” Administrative Science Quarterly 25 (1980), pp. 129–141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. 11.
    Ouchi, W. G., Theory Z (Reading: Addison-Wesley, 1981).Google Scholar
  12. 12.
    Sah, R. K., and J. E. Stiglitz, “The Architecture of Economic Systems: Hierarchies and Polyarchies,” American Economic Review 76 (1986), pp. 716–727.Google Scholar
  13. 13.
    Smith, A., An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (New York: Random House, 1937).Google Scholar
  14. 14.
    Williamson, O. E., “Hierarchical Control and Optimum Firm Size,” Journal of Political Economy 75 (1967), pp. 123–138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. 15.
    Williamson, O. E., Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications (New York: Free Press, (1975).Google Scholar
  16. 16.
    Williamson, O. E., “The Modern Corporation: Origins, Evolution, Attributes,” Journal of Economic Literature 19(1981), pp. 1537–1568.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2001

Authors and Affiliations

  • Donald W. Katzner
    • 1
  1. 1.University of MassachusettsUSA

Personalised recommendations