Skip to main content

Horizontal, Vertical, and Conglomerate Mergers

  • Chapter
  • First Online:

Part of the book series: Springer Texts in Business and Economics ((STBE))

Abstract

The immediate and most dramatic way for a company to expand its size and influence market structure is to purchase another company. Historical examples abound. In the late 1800s, Standard Oil Company gained a 90% share of the petroleum market by purchasing more than 120 competitors. In the 1960s, ITT (International Telephone and Telegraph) became a diversified corporation by acquiring 52 domestic and 55 foreign companies, including such well-known businesses as Avis Rent-a-Car, Continental Baking (Wonder Bread), Hartford Insurance, and Sheraton Hotels. By 1968, ITT had become the 11th largest corporation in the USA. The recent financial crisis has forced a number of very large acquisitions. The largest of these occurred in 2008, with Bank of America purchasing Merrill Lynch, a provider of insurance and financial services, for $50 billion and Wells Fargo Bank purchasing Wachovia Bank for $15.1 billion.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   69.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Technically, an acquisition happens when one company buys another. Acquisitions are sometimes hostile (i.e., hostile takeovers). This occurs when management of the targeted firm resists being purchased by the acquiring firm. A merger occurs when companies become a single new company. These are sometimes called “mergers of equals,” because typically the companies involved are of similar size.

  2. 2.

    Notice that product and market extension mergers are related to horizontal mergers, because the firms involved are imperfect competitors in the product extension case and potential competitors in the market extension case. Thus, they can have greater antitrust consequences, as we will see in Chap. 20.

  3. 3.

    This begs the question of how close is close, a question that is difficult to answer in practice. Certainly, vanilla ice cream and strawberry ice cream are close enough substitutes such that a merger between a supplier of vanilla and a supplier of strawberry ice cream would be considered a horizontal merger. But what about a merger between an ice cream parlor and a bakery? Clearly, judgment calls must be made.

  4. 4.

    Antitrust implications are discussed in the next chapter.

  5. 5.

    For a more complete discussion of US merger waves, see Scherer and Ross (1990) and Martin (2007a, b).

  6. 6.

    National and state corporate income tax rates are available from the Tax Foundation, http://www.taxfoundation.org/taxdata/show/23034.html.

  7. 7.

    For early discussions of this problem, see Berle et al. (1932) and Marris (1964). For more recent surveys of the principle–agent problem, see Rees (1985a, b), Eisenhardt (1989), and Shleifer and Vishny (1997).

  8. 8.

    Part of this gain could have been caused by cost efficiencies. For further discussion of this merger, see Scherer and Ross (1990) and Greer (1992).

  9. 9.

    Of course, not all models give the same prediction. In the homogeneous Bertrand model with symmetric firms, a merger short of monopoly will have no effect on prices and profits.

  10. 10.

    More precisely, the following condition must hold for a merger to be profitable, \( m \ >\ n + {1}.{5}\sqrt {{5 + 4n}} /2 \). For example, m must be greater than 80% of n when n = 5 firms, 81.5% when n = 10, and 91.4% when n = 100.

  11. 11.

    This conclusion would also hold in a Bertrand model where firms compete in price instead of output. In the Bertrand case, as long as m < n, the Bertrand price remains at marginal cost. In this model, market power is nonexistent, and a horizontal merger cannot increase market power as long as more than one firm remains.

  12. 12.

    Alternatively, this may occur because the larger firm is more patient in bargaining than the smaller firm, as we discussed in Chap. 3.

  13. 13.

    We postpone our discussion of equity issues until Chap. 19.

  14. 14.

    It involved the 1979 merger between the Xidex and Kalvar corporations, producers of microfilm. This merger was successfully challenged by the Federal Trade Commission. Barton and Sherman (1984) demonstrated that it led to higher output prices and greater market power.

  15. 15.

    For a more complete review of behavioral issues as they apply to finance, see Barberis and Thaler (2003, Farmer and Lo (1999), Lo (2004), and Malkiel (2011)).

  16. 16.

    Dafny (2009) also criticizes the event study approach for failing to correct for endogeneity. With such a correction, he finds that hospital mergers between local competitors lead to higher prices.

  17. 17.

    Other studies include Borenstein (1990) and Singal (1996).

  18. 18.

    A substantial merger was defined as one that increases the Herfindahl–Hirschman index (HHI) by at least 200 points. For example, if a market consists of ten equal size firms, they each have a market share of 10%. If two firms merge, this increases HHI by 200 points (2·10·10). That is, before the merger HHI = 1,000 (10·102), and after the merger HHI = 1,200 (202 + 8·102). See Chap. 8 for further discussion of HHI.

  19. 19.

    These were near median size for mergers of the period. Many involved conglomerate firms that also competed in a horizontal market. They include Proctor & Gamble and Tambrands (in 1997, producers of sanitary products), Guinness and Grand Metropolitan (1997, alcoholic beverages), Pennzoil and Quaker State (1998, motor oil), General Mills and Ralcorp (1997, breakfast cereal), and Aurora Foods and Craft’s Breakfast Syrup Business (1997, pancake syrup).

  20. 20.

    They used a linear programming technique, called data envelopment analysis. This technique of estimating frontier production and cost functions is discussed in Färe et al. (1985, 2008).

  21. 21.

    Complementary goods must also be available to consumers. For example, cameras need batteries, and automobiles need gas and oil.

  22. 22.

    Given that the literature is so extensive, we focus on the main benefits and costs. Other possible reasons for vertical integration include a desire to avoid taxes and regulations. For a more complete description, see Waldman and Jensen (2006, Chap. 16), Rey and Tirole (2007), and Pepall (2008, Chaps. 1719).

  23. 23.

    This derives from Smith’s (1776) insight that the division of labor is limited by the size of the market.

  24. 24.

    For further discussion, see Thomas (1977) and Langlois and Robertson (1989). Langlois and Robertson argue that Ford was later forced to vertically integrate once again due to the rapid success of its Model T and delays in delivery of key inputs.

  25. 25.

    Another solution would be to have the buyer pay in full before production is begun on a custom good. When it is costly to specify all product characteristics, this creates another problem. The seller has an incentive to cut costs by lowering quality.

  26. 26.

    Much like the welfare analysis of advertising that we discussed in Chap. 15, an increase in service quality is more likely to be welfare improving when it leads to a parallel shift in demand and is more likely to lower welfare when it rotates demand clockwise (Scherer 1983; Comanor 1985). For an excellent survey of this literature, see Waldman and Jensen (2006, Chap. 16).

  27. 27.

    We will see that the most efficient outcome is when all input and output markets are competitive.

  28. 28.

    With three stages and a monopolist at each stage, there is triple marginalism.

  29. 29.

    See Chaps. 3 and 11 for a review of the use of backwards induction to identify the SPNE.

  30. 30.

    This is sometimes called the Chicago School critique of early concerns that vertical mergers can enhance market power. As we discussed in Chap. 1, the Chicago School is skeptical that government policy can produce net social benefits. For further discussion, see Posner (1976), Bork (1978), and Riordan (1998).

  31. 31.

    A variable proportions technology is characterized by a convex isoquant. This implies a certain amount of substitutability between inputs, as with steel and aluminum in automobile production. As the price of steel increases, cost-minimizing manufacturers will substitute aluminum for steel. A fixed-proportion technology implies that inputs are perfect complements and are characterized by right-angled isoquants. This characterizes tires and car chassis. Four tires are used with each chassis, regardless of the relative prices of tires and chassis. For further discussion, see Varian (2010, Chap. 10).

  32. 32.

    This sometimes takes the form of a franchising fee (Caves and Murphy 1976; Rubin 1978). A franchise contract between a wholesaler and retailer frequently gives the retailer the legal right to sell the wholesaler’s product, requires that the wholesaler provide sales training to the retailer, specifies the level of sales effort, and specifies a nonlinear payment contract. Typically, this will include a fixed franchise fee and a split of retail revenues. Contracts such as these are common practice in the fast-food industry, where companies like McDonald’s have a franchise contract with retailers for the right to distribute McDonald’s food.

  33. 33.

    Although often used interchangeably, cement is an input for concrete. Cement is a powered substance made from limestone and clay. Concrete is produced by mixing cement, sand, gravel, and water.

  34. 34.

    This quote is taken from Stelzer (1976, 133). For further discussion of this case, see Waldman (1986).

  35. 35.

    In addition, Ordover et al. (1990) show that vertical foreclosure can harm competition when products are differentiated.

  36. 36.

    Given the benefits of learning, a merger is likely to be cheaper than opening up a brand new store, σ M ≤ σ PE. If they are unequal, this will remain a unique SPNE as long as σ M < 70 and σ PE > 30.

  37. 37.

    For a more complete discussion, see Vernon and Graham (1971), Schmalensee (1973), Blair and Kaserman (1983), and Salinger (1988).

  38. 38.

    In 1970, cigarette ads were as common as beer ads are today. Beginning in 1971, the federal government severely limit cigarette advertising, making it illegal to advertise outdoors and on television and radio (Chaloupka 2007; Iwasaki and V. Tremblay 2009).

  39. 39.

    That is, four outcomes are possible and each is equally likely to occur: (1) no eggs are broken; (2) all eggs are broken; (3) child 1 breaks the eggs but not child 2; (4) child 2 breaks the eggs but not child 1. Thus, there is a 1 in 4 chance that none of the eggs arrive safely.

  40. 40.

    Federal Trade Commission v. Procter & Gamble Co., (1967). For further discussion of this case, see Waldman (1986).

  41. 41.

    For further discussion, see Business Week (November 8, 1976) and Elzinga (1990).

  42. 42.

    When information is incomplete and monitoring costs are high, Thomas and Willig (2006) find that firms will be unwilling to link strategies across markets.

  43. 43.

    In 1988, Clorox produced laundry bleach, wood stain, restaurant equipment, bottled water, and frozen foods. For further discussion, see Levine (1988), Lappen (1988), Shao (1991), and Hamilton (1997).

  44. 44.

    For further discussion, see Newton (2006). For a list of Time Magazine’s top ten corrupt CEOs over the last decade, see http://www.time.com/time/specials/packages/completelist/0,29569,1903155,00.html#ixzz0zSZrWJXl.

  45. 45.

    See Marris (1964) and Mueller (1969) for further discussion.

  46. 46.

    PR Newswire, March 10, 2011, available at http://www.highbeam.com/doc/1G1-251110190.html/print, accessed September 20, 2010.

  47. 47.

    For a review of the psychology literature, see Malmendier and Tate (2008).

  48. 48.

    Bogan and Just (2009) argue that confirmation bias, where individuals attach too much (little) importance on information that confirms (refutes) their beliefs, can also affect a CEO’s merger decision. It is unclear whether this will lead to more or less merger activity.

  49. 49.

    For a review of the evidence, see Caves (1989), Montgomery (1994), Martin and Sayrak (2003), and Mueller (2006).

  50. 50.

    Given fixed proportions, wholesale and retail output are the same.

References

  • Alchian AA, Demsetz H (1972) Production, information costs, and economic organziation. Am Econ Rev 62:777–795

    Google Scholar 

  • Andrade G, Mitchell M, Stafford E (2001) New evidence and perspectives on mergers. J Econ Perspect 15(2):103–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashenfelter O, Hosken D (2008) The effect of mergers on consumer prices: evidence from five selected case studies. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 13859, March 2008

    Google Scholar 

  • Barberis N, Thaler R (2003) A survey of behavioral finance. In: Constantinides GM, Harris M, Stulz R (eds) Handbook of the economics of finance. Elsevier

    Google Scholar 

  • Barton DM, Sherman R (1984) The price and profit effects of horizontal merger: a case study. J Ind Econ 33:165–177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blair RD, Kaserman DL (1983) Law and economics of vertical integration and control. Academic, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Bogan V, Just D (2009) What drives merger decision making behavior? Don’t seek, don’t find, and don’t change your mind. J Econ Behav Organ 72(3):930–943

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bork RH (1978) The antitrust paradox: a policy at war with itself. Basic Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlton DW, Perloff JM (2005) Modern industrial organization. Person, Addison, Wesley, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Caves RE (1981) Diversification and seller concentration: evidence from changes, 1963–1972. Rev Econ Stat 63(2):289–293

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caves RE (1989) Mergers, takeovers, and economic efficiency: foresight and hindsight. Int J Ind Organ 7(1):151–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caves RE, Murphy WF (1976) Franchising: firms, markets, and intangible assets. Southern Econ J 42:572–586

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaloupka FJ (2007) Cigarettes: old firms facing new challenges. In: Tremblay VJ, Tremblay CH (eds) Industry and firm studies. M.E. Sharpe, Amonk, NY, pp 80–118

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase R (1937) The nature of the firm. Economica 4:386–405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Comanor WS (1985) Vertical price-fixing, vertical market restrictions, and the new antitrust policy. Harv Law Rev 98(5):983–1002

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Comanor WS, Frech HE III (1985) The competitive effects of vertical agreements. Am Econ Rev 75:539–546

    Google Scholar 

  • Creane A, Davidson C (2004) Multidivisional firms, internal competition and the merger paradox. Can J Econ 37(4):951–977

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dafny L (2009) Estimation and identification of merger effects: an application to hospital mergers. J Law Econ 52:523–550

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Long Bradford J, Shleifer A, Summers LH, Waldman RJ (1990) Noise trader risk in financial markets. J Pol Econ 98:703–738

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Long JB, Shleifer A, Summers LH, Waldman RJ (1991) The survival of noise traders in financial markets. J Bus 64(1):1–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edwards CD (1955) Conglomerate bigness as a source of power. In: Business Concentration and Price Policy. Princeton University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Egger P, Hahn FR (2010) Endogenous bank mergers and their impact on banking performance: some evidence from Austria. Int J Ind Organ 28(2):155–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eisenhardt K (1989) Agency theory: an assessment and review. Acad Manage Rev 14(1):57–74

    Google Scholar 

  • Eis C (1969) The 191901930 Merger movement in American industry. J Law Econ 12:280–284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elzinga KG (1990) The beer industry. In: Adams W (ed) The structure of American industry. MacMillan Publishing Co., New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Knox Lovell CA (1985) The measurement of efficiency of production. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Knox Lovell CA (2008) Production frontiers. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, England

    Google Scholar 

  • Fee CE, Thomas S (2004) Sources of gains in horizontal Mergers: evidence from customer, supplier, and rival firms. J Financial Econ 74(3):423–460

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Focarelli D, Panetta F (2003) Are Mergers beneficial to consumers? Evidence from the market for bank deposits. Am Econ Rev 93(4):1152–1172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham JR, Lemmon ML, Wolf JG (2002) Does corporate diversification destroy value? J Finance 42(2):695–720

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greer DF (1992) Industrial organization and public policy. MacMillan, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman SJ, Hart O (1986) The costs and benefits of ownership: a theory of vertical and lateral integration. J Polit Econ 94(4):691–719

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gugler K, Mueller DC, Burcin Yurtoglu B, Zulehner C (2003) The effects of Mergers: an international comparison. Int J Ind Organ 21(5):625–653

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gugler K, Siebert R (2007) Market power versus efficiency effects of Mergers and research joint ventures: evidence from the semiconductor industry. Rev Econ Stat 89(4):645–659

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton J (1997) Brighter days for Clorox. Business Week, June 16, 1997, 62 and 65

    Google Scholar 

  • Hart O, Moore J (1990) Property rights and the nature of the firm. J Polit Econ 98(6):1119–1158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris R, Robinson C (2002) The effect of foreign acquisitions on total factor productivity: plant-level evidence from U.K. manufacturing, 1987–1992. Rev Econ Stat 84(3):562–568

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hastings JS (2004) Vertical relationships and competition in retail gasoline markets: empirical evidence from contract changes in Southern California. Am Econ Rev 94(1):317–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hortacsu A, Syverson C (2007) Cementing relationships: vertical integration, foreclosure, productivity, and prices. J Polit Econ 115(2):250–301

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iwasaki N, Tremblay VJ (2009) The effect of marketing regulations on efficiency: LeChatelier versus coordination effects. J Prod Anal 32(1):41–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jandik T, Makhija AK (2005) Can diversification create value? Evidence from the electric utility industry. Fin Manag 34(1):61–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jans I, Rosenbaum DI (1997) Multimarket contact and pricing: evidence from the U.S. cement industry. Int J Ind Organ 15(3):391–412

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim EH, Singal V (1993) Mergers and market power: evidence from the airline industry. Am Econ Rev 83(3):549–569

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein B (1988) Vertical integration as organizational ownership: the fisher body – General motors relationship revisited. J Law Econ Organ 4:199–213

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein B, Crawford R, Alchian A (1978) Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process. J Law Econ 21:297–326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kwoka JE Jr., M Pollitt (2010) Industry restructuring, mergers, and efficiency: evidence from electric power. Int J Ind Organ, forthcoming, 2010

    Google Scholar 

  • Lafontaine F, Slade M (2007) Vertical integration and firm boundaries: the evidence. J Econ Lit 45:629–685

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langlois RN, Robertson PL (1989) Explaining vertical integration: lessons from the American automobile industry. J Econ Hist 49(2):361–375

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lappen AA (1988) Battling for a bleachhead. Forbes, November 28, 1988, 138

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine JB (1988) Clorox makes a daring move in the laundry room. Business Week, May 2, 1988, 36

    Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenberg FR (1992) Corporate takeovers and productivity. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenberg FR, Siegel D (1987) Productivity and changes in ownership of manufacturing plants. Brookings Pap Econ Act 3:643–683

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malmendier U, Tate G (2008) Who makes acquisitions? CEO overconfidence and market reaction. J Fin Econ 89:20–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manne HG (1965) Mergers and the market for corporate control. J Polit Econ 73:110–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marris R (1964) The economic theory of managerial capitalism. The Free Press, Glencoe, IL

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall WJ, Yawitz JB, Greenberg E (1984) Incentives for diversification and the structure of conglomerate firms. Southern Econ J 51(1):1–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin JD, Sayrak A (2003) Corporate diversification and shareholder value: a survey of recent literature. J Corp Fin 9(1):37–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin S (2007a) Mergers: an overview. Working paper. Department of Economics, Purdue University, IN, USA

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin S (2007b) Remembrance of things past: antitrust, ideology, and the development of industrial economics. In: Stennek J (ed) The political economy of antitrust. Emerald Group Publishing Limited, England, pp 25–57

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • May DO (1995) Do managerial motives influence firm risk reduction strategies? J Fin 50(4):1291–1309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McAfee RP, Williams MA (1988) Can event studies detect anticompetitive mergers? Econ Lett 28:199–203

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mcguckin RH, Nguyen SV (1995) On productivity and plant ownership change: new evidence from the longitudinal research database. Rand J Econ 26(2):257–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monteverde K, Teece DJ (1982) Appropriable rents and quasi-vertical integration. J Law Econ 25:403–418

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montgomery CA (1994) Corporate diversification. J Econ Perspect 8(3):163–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mortimer JH (2007) Vertical contracts in the video rental industry. Rev Econ Stud 75(1):165–199

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller DC (1969) A theory of conglomerate mergers. Quart J Econ 83(4):643–659

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller DC (2006) Corporate governance and economic performance. Int Rev Appl Econ 20(5):623–643

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newton LH (2006) Permission to steal: revealing the roots of corporate scandal, Blackwell Publishing

    Google Scholar 

  • Ordover JA, Saloner G, Salop SC (1990) Equilibrium vertical foreclosure. Am Econ Rev 80(1):127–142

    Google Scholar 

  • Overstreet TR, Price R (1983) Maintenance: economic theories and empirical evidence. FTC Bureau of Economics Staff Report, Washington D.C., November 1983

    Google Scholar 

  • Prager RA, Hannan TH (1998) Do substantial horizontal mergers generate significant price effects? Evidence from the banking industry. J Ind Econ 46(4):433–452

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ravenscraft DJ, Scherer FM (1987) Mergers, sell-offs, and economic efficiency. Brookings Institution, Washington DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Rees R (1985a) The theory of principle and agent, Part I. Bull Econ Res 37(1):3–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rees R (1985b) The theory of principle and agent, Part II. Bull Econ Res 37(2):75–97

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riordan MH (1998) Anticompetitive vertical integration by a dominant firm. Am Econ Rev 88:1232–1248

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubin PH (1978) The theory of the firm and the structure of the franchise contract. J Law Econ 21:223–233

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salant SW, Switzer S, Reynolds RJ (1983) Losses from horizontal Merger: the effects of an exogenous change in industry structure on Cournot-Nash equilibrium. Quart J Econ 98(2):185–213

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salinger MA (1988) Vertical mergers and market foreclosure. Quart J Econ 103:345–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sass TR (2005) The competitive effects of exclusive dealing: evidence from the U.S. beer industry. Int J Ind Organ 23:203–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scherer FM, Ross D (1990) Industrial market structure and economic performance. Houghton Mifflin Co., Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmalensee R (1973) A note on the theory of vertical integration. J Polit Econ 81(2):442–449

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shao M (1991) A bright idea that clorox wishes it never had. Business Week, June 24, 1991, 118–119

    Google Scholar 

  • Sherman R (1974) The economics of industry. Little Brown, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer A, Vishny RW (1989) Management entrenchment: the case of manager-specific investments. J Fin Econ 25:123–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer A, Vishny RW (1997) A survey of corporate governance. J Fin 52(2):737–783

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith A (1776) An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations

    Google Scholar 

  • Spengler JJ (1950) Vertical integration and antitrust policy. J Polit Econ 58:347–352

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler GJ (1950) Monopoly and oligopoly by merger. Am Econ Rev 40(2):23–34

    Google Scholar 

  • Thomas CJ, Willig RD (2006) The risk of contagion from multimarket contact. Int J Ind Organ 24(6):1157–1184

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomas RP (1977) An analysis of the pattern of growth of the automobile industry, 1895–1929. Arno Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Tremblay VJ, Tremblay CH (2005) The U.S. brewing industry: data and economic analysis. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Varian HR (2010) Intermediate microeconomics: a modern approach. W.W. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Vernon JM, Graham DA (1971) Profitability of monopolization by vertical integration. J Polit Econ 79(5):924–925

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Villalonga B (2004) Does diversification cause the ‘diversity discount’? Fin Manag 33(2):5–27

    Google Scholar 

  • Waldman DE (1986) The economics of antitrust: cases and analysis. Little, Brown, and Company, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Waldman DE, Jensen EJ (2006) Industrial organization: theory and practice. Person Addison-Wesley, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Whinston MD (2007) Antitrust policy toward horizontal mergers. In: Armstrong M, Porter RH (eds) Handbook of industrial organization, vol 3. Elsevier North-Holland, Boston, pp 2369–2440

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson OE (1968) Economies as an antitrust defense: the welfare trade-offs. Am Econ Rev 58(1):18–36

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson OE (1975) Markets and heirachies: analysis and antitrust implications: a study in the economics of internal organization. The Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson OE (1985) The economic institutions of capitalism: firms, markets, and relational contracting. The Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix A: The Economics of Double Marginalism

Appendix A: The Economics of Double Marginalism

Here, we formally analyze the economics of double marginalism by considering the problem described in Sect. 18.4.1.5. This is a market for gasoline with a monopoly manufacturer or wholesaler (W) and a monopoly distributor or retailer (R). Gasoline is supplied using a fixed-proportions technology. The total cost of wholesaling is TCW = c W Q, where c W is marginal and average cost and Q is output. The retailer pays the wholesale price of gasoline, and there are no added costs to the retailer of doing business. Thus, the retailer’s total cost is TCR = c R Q, where cR is the retailer’s marginal and average cost. Because there are no added costs of retailing, c R = p W, the wholesale price of gas. The inverse demand at the retail level is linear: p R = a – bQ, where p R is the retail price.Footnote 50 Firms compete in a two-stage game. In the first stage, the wholesaler sets its price. In the second stage, the retailer chooses its output level given the wholesale price of gasoline.

We use backwards induction to identify the SPNE. The problem in the second stage is for the retailer to maximize its profit (π R), given p W. The firm’s profit equation is

$$ \begin{array}{ccccccc}{\pi_{\rm{R}}} = {\hbox{T}}{{\hbox{R}}_{\rm{R}}} - {\hbox{T}}{{\hbox{C}}_{\rm{R}}} \\ = {p_{\rm{R}}}Q - {c_{\rm{R}}}Q = (aQ - b{Q^2}) - {c_{\rm{R}}}Q. \end{array} $$
(A.1)

Recalling that c R = p W, the first-order condition of profit maximization is

$$ \begin{array}{ccccccc} \frac{{\partial {\pi_{\rm{R}}}}}{{\partial Q}} = \frac{{\partial {\text{T}}{{\text{R}}_{\rm{R}}}}}{{\partial Q}} - \frac{{\partial {\text{T}}{{\text{C}}_{\rm{R}}}}}{{\partial Q}} \\ = {\hbox{M}}{{\hbox{R}}_{\rm{R}}} - {\hbox{M}}{{\hbox{C}}_{\rm{R}}} \\ = (a - 2bQ) - {p_{\rm{W}}} = 0,\end{array}$$
(A.2)

where MRR is the retailer’s marginal revenue and MCR is the retailer’s marginal cost. Solving for Q gives the retailer’s best-reply function (Q BR)

$$ {Q^{\rm{BR}}} = \frac{{a - {p_{\rm{W}}}}}{{2b}}. $$
(A.3)

Notice that if the retailer owns the wholesaler or if the wholesale price equals MCW, then this would be the simple monopoly solution.

Next, we solve the wholesaler’s problem. The wholesaler is assumed to be sequentially rational and can look forward and reason back. This enables it to identify the retailer’s best-reply and maximize its profits given Q BR. From the wholesaler’s perspective, Q BR is the wholesaler’s demand. Solving (A.3) for p W gives the wholesaler’s inverse demand: p W = a – 2bQ. Notice that it equals MRR (from A.2). The wholesaler’s profit equation is

$$ \begin{array}{ccccccc} {\pi_{\rm{W}}} = {\hbox{T}}{{\hbox{R}}_{\rm{W}}} - {\hbox{T}}{{\hbox{C}}_{\rm{W}}} \\ = {p_{\rm{W}}}{Q^{\rm{BR}}} - {c_{\rm{W}}}{Q^{\rm{BR}}} = \left( {{p_{\rm{W}}} - {c_{\rm{W}}}} \right){Q^{\rm{BR}}} \\ = \left( {{p_{\rm{W}}} - {c_{\rm{W}}}} \right)\left( {\frac{{a - {p_{\rm{W}}}}}{{2b}}} \right). \end{array}$$
(A.4)

The first-order condition with respect to p W is

$$ \begin{array}{ccccccc} \frac{{\partial {\pi_{\rm{W}}}}}{{\partial {p_{\rm{W}}}}} = \frac{{\partial {\text{T}}{{\text{R}}_{\rm{W}}}}}{{\partial {p_{\rm{W}}}}} - \frac{{\partial {\text{T}}{{\text{C}}_{\rm{W}}}}}{{\partial {p_{\rm{W}}}}} \\ = {\hbox{M}}{{\hbox{R}}_{{p{\rm{W}}}}} - {\hbox{M}}{{\hbox{C}}_{{p{\rm{W}}}}} \\ = \left( {\frac{{a - 2{p_{\rm{W}}}}}{{2b}}} \right) + \left( {\frac{{{c_{\rm{W}}}}}{{2b}}} \right) = 0, \end{array}$$
(A.5)

where MR pW is the wholesaler’s marginal revenue with respect to price, and MC pW is the wholesaler’s marginal cost with respect to price. Solving this for p W gives the profit-maximizing wholesale price. Substituting this value into Q BR and the demand and profit equations gives the other SPNE values:

$$ p_{\rm{R}}^{*} = \frac{{3a + {c_{\rm{W}}}}}{4} \,>\, p_{\rm{W}}^{*} = \frac{{a - {c_{\rm{W}}}}}{2}, $$
(A.6)
$$ {Q^{*}} = \frac{{a - {c_{\rm{W}}}}}{{4b}}, $$
(A.7)
$$ \pi_{\rm{R}}^{*} = \frac{{{{(a - {c_{\rm{W}}})}^2}}}{{16b}}\, < \,\pi_{\rm{W}}^{*} = \frac{{{{(a - {c_{\rm{W}}})}^2}}}{{8b}}, $$
(A.8)
$$ \pi_{\rm{R}}^{*} + \pi_{\rm{W}}^{*} = \frac{{3{{(a - {c_{\rm{W}}})}^2}}}{{16b}}. $$
(A.9)

If the firms were to merge, this would produce the simple monopoly solution:

$$ p_{\rm{R}}^{{**}} = \frac{{a + {c_{\rm{W}}}}}{2}, $$
(A.10)
$$ {Q^{{**}}} = \frac{{a - {c_{\rm{W}}}}}{{2b}}, $$
(A.11)
$$ {\pi^{{**}}} = \frac{{4{{(a - {c_{\rm{W}}})}^2}}}{{16b}}. $$
(A.12)

This demonstrates the principle of double marginalism: compared to a single merged firm, separate wholesale and retail monopolies are (1) less efficient because Q ** > Q *; (2) less profitable (\( {\pi^{{**}}}\, >\, \pi_{\rm{R}}^{*} + \pi_{\rm{W}}^{*} \)), providing an incentive for vertical merger; (3) bad for consumers, because the retail price is lower and production is greater with the merger. Notice too that this problem is similar to the problem of complementary products that we discussed in Chap. 13.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2012 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Tremblay, V.J., Tremblay, C.H. (2012). Horizontal, Vertical, and Conglomerate Mergers. In: New Perspectives on Industrial Organization. Springer Texts in Business and Economics. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-3241-8_18

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics