Skip to main content

Energy Pricing and Taxation

  • Chapter
  • First Online:

Abstract

This chapter introduces the economic concepts related to pricing of energy in different market conditions. The chapter starts with the basic competitive market model and discusses the extensions required to analyse specific features (such as indivisibility of capital , specificity of assets, capital intensiveness, etc.) of the energy sector. The chapter also covers the issue of market failure and presents the commonly used market interventions in such situations. The concept of cost-benefit analysis is used as the framework for most of the analysis. The principles of energy pricing are then introduced and the economic rationale behind energy taxation is considered.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   69.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    This presentation follows Rees (1984). Also see Munasinghe (1985).

  2. 2.

    In mathematical terms, \( \frac{dAC}{dQ} = \frac{{d\left( {\frac{TC}{Q}} \right)}}{dQ} = \frac{{Q \cdot \frac{dTC}{dQ} - TC}}{{Q^{2} }} = \frac{Q \cdot MC - TC}{{Q^{2} }} = 0 ; \)

  3. 3.

    Please refer to Chap. 8 for further details.

  4. 4.

    The total revenue is given by TR = P·Q, where P = price and Q = output. Marginal revenue is then \( \frac{dTR}{dQ} = P + Q\frac{dP}{dQ} \), or MR = P(1 + 1/e), where MR = marginal revenue and e = price elasticity of demand. As e is less than 1, MR is less than P.

  5. 5.

    Economies of scope imply the potential of cost saving from joint production. This is possible because the firm can make better use of facilities and services for producing a certain mix of different outputs than leaving the production of individual products to specialty firms.

  6. 6.

    Interested readers may consult the following: Diamond and Mirrlees (1971), Feldstein (1972).

  7. 7.

    However, the market failure argument has been subjected to serious scrutiny. See Robinson (2004) for such a viewpoint.

  8. 8.

    See OECD database at http://www2.oecd.org/ecoinst/queries/index.htm.

  9. 9.

    See Mankiw et al. (2009) for a recent review. See also Newbery and Stern (1988), Diamond and Mirrlees (1971) and Feldstein (1972).

  10. 10.

    See Pearce et al. (1994) for more details.

References

  • Andersson, R., & Bohman, M. (1985, October). Short- and long-run marginal cost pricing: on their alleged equivalence. Energy Economics, 279–288.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J., & Bradford, D. F. (1970). Optimal departures from marginal cost pricing. American Economic Review, 60(3), 265–283.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharyya, S. C. (1995). Internalising externalities of energy use through price mechanism: A developing country perspective. Energy & Environment, 6(3), 211–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharyya, S. C. (1996). Domestic energy pricing policies in developing countries: Why are economic prescriptions shelved? Energy Sources, 18, 855–874.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharyya, S. C. (1997, Spring). Energy taxation and environmental externalities: A critical analysis. International Journal of Energy and Development, 22(2), 199–223.

    Google Scholar 

  • Birol, F. (2007). Energy economics: A place for energy poverty in the agenda? Energy Journal, 28(3), 1–6.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boiteux, M. (1956, January 24). Sur la gestion des monopoles publics astreints a l’equilibre budgetaire. Econometrica, 22–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bose, S. (1993). Money, energy and welfare: The state and the households in India’s rural electrification policy. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boskin, M. J., & Robinson, M. S. (1986). Energy taxes and optimal tax theory. The Energy Journal, 1986(Special Issue), 1–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, P. A., & Mirrlees, J. A. (1971). Optimal taxation and public production, II: Tax rules. American Economic Review.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein, M. S. (1972, May). Distributional equity and the optimal structure of public prices. American Economic Review, 32–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griffin, J. F., & Steele, H. B. (1980). Energy economics and policy. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • IEA. (1996). The role of IEA governments in energy. Paris: International Energy Agency. http://www.iea.org/textbase/nppdf/free/1990/role_energy1996.pdf.

  • IEA. (2017). World energy outlook 2017. Paris: International Energy Agency.

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF. (2013). Energy subsidy reform: Lessons and implications. Washington DC: International Monetary Fund. Retrieved July 25, 2018 https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/Policy-Papers/Issues/2016/12/31/Energy-Subsidy-Reform-Lessons-and-Implications-PP4741.

  • Kumar, M. S. (1985). Socio-economic goals in energy pricing policy: A framework for analysis. In C. M. Siddayao (Ed.), Criteria for energy pricing. London: Graham & Trotman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leibenstein, H. (1966). Allocative efficiency vs. x-efficiency. American Economic Review, 56, 392–415.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, N. G., Weinzierl, M., & Yagan, D. (2009). Optimal taxation in theory and practice. NBER Working paper no. 15071. Cambridge, MA, USA: The National Bureau of Economic Research. http://www.nber.org/papers/w15071.

  • Munasinghe, M., & Warford, J. J. (1982). Electricity pricing: Theory and case studies. Washington DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Munasinghe, M. (1985). Energy pricing and demand management. Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nan, G. D. (1995). An energy Btu tax alternative. Resource and Energy Economics, 17(3), 291–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newbery, D., & Stern, N. (Eds.). (1988). The theory of taxation for developing countries. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pandey, R. (2002). Energy Policy modeling: Agenda for developing countries. Energy Policy, 30, 97–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pearce, D., Turner, K., & Bateman, I. (1994). Environmental economics: An elementary introduction. John Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rangaswamy, V. (1989). Domestic energy pricing policies. Energy Series Paper 13. Washington DC: World Bank (World Bank, 2004, Reforming infrastructure: Privatisation, regulation and competition, World Bank). Retrieved January 5, 2005 from http://econ.worldbank.org/files/36237_complete.pdf.

  • Rees, R. (1984). Public Enterprise Economics. London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, C. (2004). MARKETS, IMPER FECTIONS AND THE DANGERS OF OVER‐REGULATING ENERGY MARKETS. Economic Affairs, 24(2), 52-55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schramm, G. (1991). Marginal cost pricing revisited. Energy economics, 13(4), 245-249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shukla, P. R. (1995). Greenhouse gas models and abatement costs for developing countries: A critical assessment. Energy Policy, 23(8), 677–687.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • The House of Lords. (2017). The price of power: Reforming the electricity market. In Select committee of economic affairs. London: The House of Lords. Retrieved July 25, 2018 from https://publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld201617/ldselect/ldeconaf/113/113.pdf.

  • Turvey, R. (1968). Optimal pricing and investment in electricity supply: Allen and Unwin, London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turvey, R. (1969). Marginal cost. The Economic Journal, 79(314), 282-299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K., Harrington, J. E., & Vernon, j. M. (2005). Economics of regulation and antitrust. Massachusetts: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weisman, D. (1991, October). A note on first-best marginal cost measures in public enterprise. Energy Economics, 250–253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism: Firms, markets, relational contracting. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2004). Reforming infrastructure: Privatisation, regulation and competition. World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Subhes C. Bhattacharyya .

Annex 9.1: Peak Load Pricing Principle

Annex 9.1: Peak Load Pricing Principle

In what follows, we use a simple example to illustrate the pricing principle for peak and off-peak periods. This follows Munasinghe and Warford (1982, Appendix C).

Suppose that the annual load duration curve of the electric utility is composed of two distinct periods (see Fig. 9.25):

  • An off-peak period during which the base load plants (using coal, nuclear, etc.) are used to supply the power. For simplicity it is assumed that the cost characteristics of these plants are uniform. The fixed cost per kW of capacity is a and the variable cost per hour is f. Assume also that the base capacity is given by X kW.

  • A peak-period during which peaking plants are called to supplement power supply from the base load plants. The fixed cost per kW of capacity is b and the running cost per hour is g. Total load is Y kW, which implies that Y-X is the peak load capacity.

Fig. 9.25
figure 25

Load duration curve for the example

It is assumed as usual that a > b but f < g. It is also assumed that the entire capacity is fully utilised.

For any duration, h, the cost of using 1 kW of capacity of base plant is given by

$$ {\text{y}} = {\text{a}} + {\text{f}}\,*\,{\text{h}}, $$
(9.21)

whereas for the peak plant the cost is given by

$$ {\text{z}} = {\text{b}} + {\text{g}}\,*\,{\text{h}} $$
(9.22)

Given the cost characteristics, there exists a point where the costs of using the two types of plants are equal, i.e. y = z. This point indicates a number of hours during which the peaking plant shall be operated. By equating 9.21 and 9.2, this duration is obtained as follows:

$$ {\text{H}} = \left( {{\text{a}} - {\text{b}}} \right)/\left( {{\text{g}} - {\text{f}}} \right) = {\text{difference in fixed costs}}/{\text{difference in variable costs}}. $$
(9.23)

This is shown in Fig. 9.26.

Fig. 9.26
figure 26

Screening curve

The cost of supplying the load as shown in Fig. 9.26 can be written as:

$$ {\text{C}} = {\text{X}}\left( {{\text{a}} + {\text{f}} \cdot {\text{T}}} \right) + \left( {{\text{Y}} - {\text{X}}} \right)\left( {{\text{b}} + {\text{g}} \cdot {\text{H}}} \right) $$
(9.24)

where T is the total hours in a year (8760).

We are now going to analyse how the cost changes due to changes in peak and off-peak demand.

Case 1: Peak load demand changes by 1 kW

As the installed capacity is fully used, when the peak load demand increases by 1 kW, the utility has to install an additional peak capacity of 1 kW. This is shown by the coloured rectangle above Y. The new cost of production is given by:

$$ {\text{C}}1 = {\text{X}}\left( {{\text{a}} + {\text{f}} \cdot {\text{T}}} \right) + \left( {{\text{Y}} + 1 - {\text{X}}} \right)\left( {{\text{b}} + {\text{g}} \cdot {\text{H}}} \right) $$
(9.25)
$$ {\text{The incremental cost is}}\,\Delta {\text{C}}1 = {\text{C}}1 - {\text{C}} = {\text{b}} + {\text{g}} \cdot {\text{H}} $$
(9.26)

This suggests that an additional demand during the peak period leads to two types of costs: the fixed cost and the running cost and the consumers should bear these costs if the tariff has to be cost-reflective.

Case 2: Demand increases during off-peak period

As the off-peak capacity is fully used, the utility has to install 1 kW of off-peak capacity. As the off-peak capacity will be available for peak load as well, the peak capacity will be reduced by 1 kW. The cost of supply can be written as:

$$ {\text{C}}2 = \left( {{\text{X}} + 1} \right)\left( {{\text{a}} + {\text{f}} \cdot {\text{T}}} \right) + \left[ {Y - \left( {X + 1} \right)} \right]\left( {b + g \cdot H} \right) $$
(9.27)

The incremental cost is given by

$$ \Delta {\text{C}}2 \, = {\text{ C}}2 \, {-}{\text{C}} = \left( {{\text{a}} + {\text{f}} \cdot {\text{T}}} \right){-}\left( {{\text{b}} + {\text{g}}.{\text{H}}} \right) = \left( {{\text{a}} - {\text{b}}} \right) + \left( {{\text{f}} \cdot {\text{T}}{-}{\text{ g}} \cdot {\text{H}}} \right) $$
(9.28)

From Eq. 9.27, (a − b) = (g − f).H

Replacing Eq. 9.27 in Eq. 9.28, we get

$$ \Delta {\text{C}}2 = {\text{f}} \cdot \left( {{\text{T}} - {\text{H}}} \right) $$
(9.29)

The supplementary cost is equal to the cost of running the off-peak capacity during the off-peak hours (T − H). There is no fixed cost attached here and hence consumers coming to the grid during off-peak hours should pay only the running cost.

Case 3: Demand increases during the entire period

In this case, the total demand increases by 1 kW throughout. The total cost of supply is given by:

$$ {\text{C}}3 = \left( {{\text{X}} + 1} \right)\left( {{\text{a}} + {\text{f}} \cdot {\text{T}}} \right) + \left( {{\text{Y}} - {\text{X}}} \right)\left( {{\text{b}} + {\text{g}} \cdot {\text{H}}} \right) $$
(9.30)

Hence, the incremental cost is given by

$$ \Delta {\text{C}}3 = {\text{a}} + {\text{f}} \cdot {\text{T}} . $$
(9.31)

This suggests that the total incremental cost of supply has to be borne by the consumers in this case.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer-Verlag London Ltd., part of Springer Nature

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Bhattacharyya, S.C. (2019). Energy Pricing and Taxation. In: Energy Economics. Springer, London. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4471-7468-4_9

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics