Skip to main content

Physiocrats and Laws of Population

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Physiocracy, Antiphysiocracy and Pfeiffer

Part of the book series: The European Heritage in Economics and the Social Sciences ((EHES,volume 10))

  • 519 Accesses

Abstract

This essay deals not with the whole theory of Physiocrats. In the following, it only referred to the special aspect, which contribution physiocratic theory has brought forth to study rules and patterns of population and to what extend Physiocrats contributed to the development of population theory.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Armengaud, André (1971), p 129.

  2. 2.

    This model was introduced by Notestein (1945), which analyzed crude birth rates and crude death rates from the middle age to the mid of the twentieth century. It is a descriptive model and does not fulfill claims of scientific theory (see for example: Hummel (2000)).

  3. 3.

    Justus von Liebig (1803–1873) is considered to be the founder of agricultural chemistry. He was a professor at the Ludwigs University of Gießen from 1824 to 1852, which later was named Justus Liebig University. Johann August Schlettwein (the leading German Physiocrat) was a professor at the Ludwigs University of Gießen from 1777 to 1785 (Justus von Liebig was not a good pupil and records indicate that his teacher said to his parents: Your son will become nothing (in Hessian language: “aus dem Bub werd nix”)).

  4. 4.

    Süßmilch (1741/Faksimile 2001).

  5. 5.

    Süßmilch (1741/Faksimile 2001), §64.

  6. 6.

    Conring (1606–1681) was a professor of nature philosophy and besides other an academic for policy in Helmstedt (1650). He wrote in his book Thesaurus totius orbis quadripartibus (1675): “Pertinet ad cognitionem hominum ut sciamus eorum numerus civium sit magnus vel parvus,” quoted from Mols (1971), p 18.

  7. 7.

    Achenwall (1719–1772) was historian, lawyer, and professor at the University of Göttingen (Lower Saxonia).

  8. 8.

    Graunt (1620–1674) was a business man in London.

  9. 9.

    Süßmilch (1707–1767).

  10. 10.

    Malthus (1766–1834) was a professor of history and political economy since 1805.

  11. 11.

    Malthus (1798).

  12. 12.

    Ricardo (1772–1823).

  13. 13.

    A relatively unknown representative is Joseph Lang, born in Germany and Professor in Charkow (Russia). He published in 1811 a book “Grundlinien der politischen Arithmetik.”

  14. 14.

    Smith (1723–1790) met considerable physiocrats on a trip through France and Switzerland in the years 1764–1766.

  15. 15.

    An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations.

  16. 16.

    Quesnay (1694–1774), French physician and economist, was a private physician of Ludwig XV. and of Madame de Pompadour.

  17. 17.

    Uebe (1992).

  18. 18.

    Schlettwein (1731–1802) was a professor at the University of Basel in 1776 and professor of policy, science of cameralistics and science of finances at the University of Gießen from 1777 to 1785.

  19. 19.

    Schlettwein (1784/1980) § 69.

  20. 20.

    Schlettwein (1779).

  21. 21.

    Schlettwein (1784/1980) §§ 74, 75.

  22. 22.

    Schlettwein (1784/1980) §§ 86.

  23. 23.

    Schlettwein (1784/1980) § 224.

  24. 24.

    Schlettwein (1784/1980) § 225.

  25. 25.

    See 18th Heilbronn Symposium, 16–18, 2005.

  26. 26.

    Schlettwein (1784/1980) § 223, rightly counted 232.

  27. 27.

    Schlettwein (1784/1980) § 234.

  28. 28.

    von Pfeiffer (1780), pp 98/99.

  29. 29.

    Schlettwein (1784/1980) § 246.

  30. 30.

    Schlettwein (1784/1980) § 241.

  31. 31.

    Schlettwein (1784/1980) § 236.

  32. 32.

    Schlettwein (1784/1980) § 240.

  33. 33.

    Schlettwein (1784/1980) §§ 261, 262.

  34. 34.

    Schlettwein (1784/1980) §§ 268, 280.

  35. 35.

    Schlettwein (1784/1980) §§ 225.

  36. 36.

    von Pfeiffer (1780), pp 23/24.

  37. 37.

    von Pfeiffer (1780), pp 22.

  38. 38.

    von Pfeiffer (1780), p 100.

  39. 39.

    Malthus (1798).

  40. 40.

    Blaich (1983), p 35.

References

  • Armengaud A (1971) Die Bevölkerung Europas von 1700–1914. In: Cipolla CM, Borchardt K (Hg) Bevölkerungsgeschichte Europas. Mittelalter bis Neuzeit. Aus dem englischen übersetzt von Anjuta Dünnwald. Drei Aufsätze aus: The Fontana Economic History of Europe. R. Piper, München, pp 123–180

    Google Scholar 

  • Blaich F (1983) Der Beitrag der deutschen Physiokraten für die Entwicklung der Wirtschaftswissenschaft von der Kameralistik zur Nationalökonomie. In: Scherf H (Hrsg) Studien zur Entwicklung der ökonomischen Theorie III; Schriften des Vereins für Socialpolitik, Gesellschaft für Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften, Neue Folge Band 115/III. Ducker & Humblodt, Berlin, pp 9–38

    Google Scholar 

  • Hummel D (2000) Der Bevölkerungsdiskurs. Demographisches Wissen und politische Macht. Leske+Budrich, Opladen, p 224

    Google Scholar 

  • Malthus TR (1798) An essay on the principle of population, as it affects the future of society. Murray, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Mols, Roger (1971) Die Bevölkerung Europas 1500–1700. In: Cipolla CM (Hrsg) deutsche Ausgabe herausgegeben von K. Borchardt: Europäische Wirtschafts-geschichte. The Fontana Economic History in 5 Bänden; Band 2: Sechzehntes und siebzehntes Jahrhundert. R. Piper, München

    Google Scholar 

  • Notestein FW (1945) Population – the long view. In: Schulz T (ed) Food for the world. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 36–57

    Google Scholar 

  • Schlettwein JA (1980) Die Rechte der Menschen oder der einzige wahre Grund aller Gesetze, Ordnungen und Verfassungen, bey Justus Friedrich Kriegen, Gießen 1784; Faksimiledruck, Scriptor

    Google Scholar 

  • Schlettwein JA (1779) Grundfeste der Staaten oder die politische Ökonomie. bey Justus Friedrich Kriegen, Gießen

    Google Scholar 

  • Süßmilch JP (2001) Die göttliche Ordnung in den Veränderungen des menschlichen Geschlechts, aus der Geburt, dem Tod und der Fortpflanzung desselben erwiesen; Berlin 1741, Faksimile-Ausgabe, Verlag Wirtschaft und Finanzen, Düsseldorf

    Google Scholar 

  • Uebe G (1992) The model of lang – national income accounts in 1807; computers mathematical application, vol 24, no. 8/9. Press Ltd, UK, pp 167–179

    Google Scholar 

  • von Pfeiffer J (1780) Der Antiphysiocrat oder die umständliche Untersuchung des sogenannten physiokratischen Systems vermöge welchem eine allgemeine Freiheit, und einzige Auflage, auf den reinen Ertrag der Grundstücke, die Glückseligkeit aller Staaten ausmachen soll; im Verlag der Eßlingerischen Buchandlung, Frankfurt am Main

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gerhard Scheuerer .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2011 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Scheuerer, G. (2011). Physiocrats and Laws of Population. In: Backhaus, J. (eds) Physiocracy, Antiphysiocracy and Pfeiffer. The European Heritage in Economics and the Social Sciences, vol 10. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4419-7497-6_7

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics