Skip to main content

Macro-dynamic Environments of the Meso Realm

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Theoretical Principles of Sociology, Volume 3
  • 873 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter visualizes the macrorealm of social reality as a sociocultural environment of corporate and categoric units of the mesolevel realm. This environment imposes constraints on the operation of groups, organizations, communities, and categoric units. These constraints can be cultural, revolving around technologies, traditions, texts, values, ideologies, generalized symbolic media, and norms, or structural, revolving around the patterns of social relations evident in institutional domains, stratification systems, societies, and even intersocietal systems. Generalized symbolic media are given special emphasis because these are the media that are used in discourse and ideological formation within institutional domains (e.g., economy, kinship, religion, and education), the valued resources that are unequally distributed, and the resources exchanged among individual and collective actors within and between institutional domains. At a more structural level, modes of integration among social units are emphasized, and depending upon the configuration of these modes used, the environment of corporate and categoric units will vary. Modes of integration include segmentation, structural differentiation, structural interdependencies (e.g., exchange, overlaps, mobility, and embedding), structural domination, and structural segregation. Emphasis is placed upon how environments at the macrolevel of social reality evolve under selection pressures upon actors to solve problems facing a population.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

     It could be argued that even nomadic hunter-gatherers had incipient community structures because they almost always had a sense of their home range and of the bands that “belonged” in this range. And early in societal evolution, community appeared when hunter-gatherers began to settle down, perhaps in temporary locations but eventually for good.

  2. 2.

     For references on the emergence and operation of status beliefs, see: Berger 1958; Berger et. al. 1972, 1977, 1980; Berger and Conner 1969; Berger and Zelditch 1985; Ridgeway 1998, 2000, 2001, 2006; Ridgeway et al. 1998, 2009; Ridgeway and Berger 1986, 1988; Ridgeway and Correll 2004; Ridgeway and Erickson 2000.

  3. 3.

     It is rather remarkable how the new institutionalism has come to dominate organizational analysis, but perhaps even more remarkable is the lack of criticism from “old institutionalists” about the limitation of institutional theorizing in the field of organizations. For a sampling of basic references in the new institutionalism, see DiMaggio (1986), DiMaggio and Powell (1983), Powell and DiMaggio (1991), Fligstein (1990, 1996), Jepperson (1991), Meyer and Rowan (1977), Hirsch (1997), Hodgson (1996), Scott and Meyer (1983), Zucker (1988), Scott (1987, 2005, 2008), Scott and Christensen (1995), Thornton (2004), and Tolbert and Zucker (1996). On the other side, there have been relatively few critiques of this larger literature on the new institutionalism. Among the few critiques, see Friedland and Alford (1991) and Abrutyn and Turner (2011).

  4. 4.

     See volume 1 of Theoretical Principles of Sociology (2010: 41–104) for a review of these forces. For earlier statements, see: Turner (1995: 1–75), (2003:23–56).

  5. 5.

     The more structural and cultural variation evident in a sociocultural formation, the more selection has something to work on. Conversely, the less variation, the less selection has to select on, if pressures for change arise. Moreover, cultural systems with little variation are often rigid and inflexible, especially if they have been highly moralized. Conversely, when cultural systems have a great deal of variation, they are generally less rigid, and thus, even if existing variants are not fitness enhancing, they are less likely to inhibit efforts at innovation by actors responding to selection pressures.

  6. 6.

     Critical theorists like Jurgen Habermas (1972) and some postmodernists argue that this circulation of money and other, in Habermas’ terms, “delinguistified media,” colonize the lifeworld of actors and disrupt if not destroy what is meaningful in other noneconomic domains. I think that these theorists overdo this claim because it is clear to me, at least, that the symbolic media of domains in which cooler media also circulate seem to sustain their cultures and traditions. Moreover, in the spirit of Simmel (1978[1907]), these critical theorists underestimate the integrative effects of media like money, as I have also emphasized in a somewhat different way than Simmel. Generalized symbolic media and their cultures become mixed and often equivalent, thereby giving people common worldviews and hence ability to form meaningful relationships with diverse actors within and between institutional domains.

References

  • Abrutyn, S. 2011. “Towards a General Theory of Institutional Autonomy.” Sociological Theory 27: 449-65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abrutyn, S. and J. H. Turner. 2011. “The Old Institutionalism Meets the New Institutionalism.” Sociological Perspectives, in press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arnold, J. E. 1992. “Complex Hunter-Gatherer-Fishers of Prehistoric California: Chiefs, Specialists, and Maritime Adaptations of the Channel Islands.” American Antiquity 57:60-84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arnold, J. E. 1993. “Labor and the Rise of Complex Hunter-Gatherers.” Journal of Anthropological Archaeology 12:75-119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arnold, J. E. 1995a. “Transportation Innovation and Social Complexity among Maritime Hunter-Gatherer Societies.” American Anthropologist 97:733-747.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arnold, J. E. 1995b. “Social Inequality, Marginalization, and Economic Process.” In Foundations of Social Inequality, T.D. Price and G.M. Feinman eds., pp. 87-103. Plenum, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arnold, J. E (editor).1996a. Emergent Complexity: The Evolution of Intermediate Societies. International Monographs In Prehistory, Ann Arbor.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arnold, J. E. 1996b. “The Archaeology of Complex Hunter-Gatherers.” Journal of Archaeological Method and Theory 3:77-126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, J. 1958. “Relations Between Performance, Rewards, and Action-Opportunities in Small Groups.” Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger, J. and T. L. Conner. 1969. “Performance Expectations and Behavior in Small Groups.” Acta Sociologica 12:186-98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, J., and M. Zelditch, Eds. 1985. Status, Rewards, and Influence. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blalock, H. M. 1967. Toward a Theory of Minority Group Relations. New York: Wiley

    Google Scholar 

  • Bonacich, E. 1973. “A Theory of Middleman Minorities.” American Sociological Review 38: 583-94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Braudel, Fernand. 1977. Afterthoughts on Material Civilization and Capitalism, translated by P. M. Ranum. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Braudel, Fernand. [1979] 1982. The Wheels of Commerce, volume 2, Civilization and Capitalism 15th–18th Century. New York: Harper/Collins.

    Google Scholar 

  • Collins, R. 1990. “Market Dynamics as the Engine of Historical Change.” Sociological Theory 8: 111-135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coser, Lewis A. 1956. The Functions of Social Conflict. London: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio, P. J. 1986. “Structural Analysis of Organizational Fields.” In Research in Organization Behavior, volume 8, B. M. Staw and L. L. Cummings, Eds. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio, P. J. and W. W. Powell. 1983. “The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organization Fields.” American Sociological Review 48: 147-60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fligstein, N. 1990. The Transformation of Corporate Control. Cambridge, M.A: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedland, R. and R. Alford. 1991. “Bringing Society Back In: Symbols, Practices, and Institutional Contradictions.” In The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. W. Powell and P. J. DiMaggio, Eds. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Habermas, J. 1973 [1976]. Legitimation Crisis. Trans. by T. McCarthy. London: Heinemann.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hannan, M. T. and J. H. Freeman. 1977. “The Population Ecology of Organizations.” American Journal of Sociology 82: 929-64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hannan, M. T. and J. H. Freeman. 1984. “Structural Inertia and Organizational Change.” American Sociological Review 49: 149-64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hannan, M. T. and J. H. Freeman. 1989. Organizational Ecology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirsch, P. M. 1997. “Review Essay: Sociology Without Social Structure: Neoinstitutional Theory Meets Brave New World.” American Journal of Sociology 102: 1702-23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jepperson, R. L. 1991. “Institutions, Institutional Effects, and Institutionalism.” In The New Institutionalism of Organizational Analysis, W.W. Powell and P. J. DiMiaggio, Eds. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luhmann, Niklas. 1982. The Differentiation of Society. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, J. W. and B. Rowan. 1977. “Institutionalized Organizations: Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony.” American Journal of Sociology 83: 340-63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parsons, T. 1963a. “On the Concept of Power.” Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society 107:232-62.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parsons, T. 1963b.“On the Concept of Influence.” Public Opinion Quarterly 27:37-62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parsons, T. 1966. Societies: Evolutionary and Comparative Perspectives. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parsons, T. and N. J. Smelser. 1956. Economy and Society. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell, W. W. and P.J. DiMaggio. Eds. 1991. The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ridgeway, C. 1998. “Where Do Status Beliefs Come From?” In Status, Network, and Structure. J Szmatka and J. Berger. Eds. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ridgeway, C. 2000. “The Formation of Status Beliefs: Improving Status Construction Theory.” Advances in Group Processes 17:77-102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ridgeway, C. 2001. “Inequality, Status, and the Construction of Status Beliefs.” Pp. 323-42 in the Handbook of Sociological Theory, J. Turner, Ed. New York: Kluwer Academic/Plenum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ridgeway, C. 2006. “Status and Emotions From an Expectation States Theory.” In Handbook of The Sociology of Emotions. J. E. Stets and J. H. Turner, Eds. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ridgeway, C. L., K.Backor, Y. E. Li, J. E. Tinkler, and K. G. Erickson. 2009. “How Easily Does a Social Difference Become a Status Distinction: Gender Matters.” American Sociological Review 74: 44-62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ridgeway, C. L. and J. Berger. 1986. “Expectations, legitimacy, and Dominance in Task Groups.” American Sociological Review 51: 603-17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ridgeway, C., E. Boyle, K. Kulpers, and D. Robinson. 1998. “How Do Status Beliefs Develop? The Role of Resources and Interaction.” American Sociological Review 63:331-50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ridgeway, C. and S. J. Correll. 2004. “Unpacking the Gender System: A Theoretical Perspective on Cultural Beliefs and Social Relations.” Gender and Society 18:

    Google Scholar 

  • Ridgeway, C. and K. G. Erickson. 2000. “Creating and Spreading Status Beliefs.” American Journal of Sociology 106:579-615.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sailer, Lee Douglas. 1978. “Structural Equivalence.” Social Networks 1: 73-90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scott, W. R. 1987. “The Adolescence of Institutional Theory.” Administrative Science Quarterly 32: 493-511.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scott, W. R. 2005. “Institutional Theory: Contributing to a Theoretical Research Program.” In Great Minds in Management: The Process of Theory Development. K. G. Smith and M. A. Hitt, Eds. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thornton, P. H. 2004. Markets from Culture: Institutional Logics and Organizational Decisions in Higher Education Publishing. Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tolbert, P. S. and L. Zucker. 1996. “The Institutionalization of Institutional Theory.” In Handbook of Organization Studies. S. R. Glegg, C. Hardy, and W. R. Nord, Eds. London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turner, J.H. 1972. Patterns of Social Organization: A Survey of Social Institutions. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turner, J.H. 1984. Social Stratification: A Theoretical Analysis. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turner, J.H. 1997. The Institutional Order: Economy, Kinship, Religion, Polity, Law, and Education in Evolutionary and Comparative Perspective. New York: Longman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turner, J.H. 2003. Human Institutions: A Theory of Societal Evolutions. Boulder: Rowman and Littlefield.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turner, J.H. 2010a. Theoretical Principles of Sociology, volume 1 on Macrodynamics. New York: Springer

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Turner, J. H. and E. Bonacich. 1980. “Toward a Composite Theory of Middleman Minorities.” Ethnicity 7: 144-58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. [1922] 1968. Economy and Society. Trans. G. Roth and C. Wittch. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, H. 1981. “Where Do Markets Come From?” American Journal of Sociology 87: 517-47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • White, H. 1988. “Varieties of Markets.” In B. Wellman and S. D. Berkowitz, eds. Structural Sociology. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zucker, L. G. ed., 1988. Institutionalized Patterns and Organizations: Culture and Environment. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2012 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Turner, J.H. (2012). Macro-dynamic Environments of the Meso Realm. In: Theoretical Principles of Sociology, Volume 3. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4419-6221-8_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics