Advertisement

An Update to the Individual-Opportunity Nexus

  • Jonathan T. Eckhardt
  • Scott Shane
Chapter
Part of the International Handbook Series on Entrepreneurship book series (IHSE, volume 5)

Abstract

This chapter extends and elaborates the individual-opportunity nexus framework on entrepreneurship. First, the chapter discusses in detail the existence of entrepreneurial opportunities, and the processes of opportunity discovery and exploitation. Second, the chapter describes several typologies of opportunities. Third, the chapter discusses the importance of the locus of opportunity discovery and exploitation.

Keywords

Social Capital Information Asymmetry Resource Provider Entrepreneurial Opportunity Entrepreneurial Process 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Notes

Acknowledgements

A version of portions of this chapter originally appeared in the Journal of Management in 2003 under the title, “Opportunities and Entrepreneurship.” The first author gratefully acknowledges research support that was provided by the Ewing Marion Kauffman Foundation’s Junior Faculty Fellows program.

References

  1. Akerlof, G. 1970. The market for lemons: Quality, uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84: 4889–5000.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Aldrich, H., & Zimmer, C. 1986. Entrepreneurship through social networks. In D. Sexton, & R. Smilor (Eds.), The Art and Science of Entrepreneurship. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Company.Google Scholar
  3. Alvarez, S. A., & Barney, J. 2007. Discovery and creation: Alternative theories of entrepreneurial action. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, 1(1–2): 11–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Amit, R., Glosten, L., & Muller, E. 1990. Entrepreneurial ability, venture investments, and risk sharing. Management Science, 36(10): 1232–1245.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Amit, R., Glosten, L., & Muller, E. 1993. Challenges to theory development in entrepreneurship research. Journal of Management Studies, 30(5): 815–834.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Anand, B., & Khanna, T. 2000. The structure of licensing contracts. Journal of Industrial Economics, 48(1): 103–135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Arrow, K. 1962. Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In R. Nelson (Ed.), The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity: Economic and Social Factors: 609–619. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  8. Arrow, K. 1974. Limited knowledge and economic analysis. American Economic Review, 64(1): 1–10.Google Scholar
  9. Audretsch, D. 1997. Technological regimes, industrial demography, and the evolution of industrial structures. Industrial and Corporate Change, 6(1): 49–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Azoulay, P., & Shane, S. 2001. Entrepreneurs, contracts, and the failure of young firms. Management Science, 47(3): 337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Bandura, A. 1997. Self-efficacy: The Exercise of Self Control. New York, NY: W. H. Freedman & Company.Google Scholar
  12. Bankman, J., & Gilson, R. 1999. Why start-ups? Stanford Law Review, 51: 289.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Barney, J. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1): 99–121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Baron, R. A. 2002. OB and entrepreneurship: The reciprocal benefits of closer conceptual links. Research in Organizational Behavior, 24: 225–269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Baron, R. A., & Ensley, M. D. 2006. Opportunity recognition as the detection of meaningful patterns: Evidence from comparisons of novice and experienced entrepreneurs. Management Science, 52(9): 1331–1344.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Baumol, W. J. 1990. Entrepreneurship: Productive, unproductive, and destructive. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5): 893–921.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Becker, G., & Murphy, K. 1992. The division of labor, coordination costs and knowledge. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107: 1137–1160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Begley, T. 1995. Using founder status, age of firm, and company growth rate as the basis of distinguishing entrepreneurs from managers of smaller businesses. Journal of Business Venturing, 10: 249–263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Begley, T., & Boyd, D. 1987. A comparison of entrepreneurs and managers of small business firms. Journal of Management, 13: 99–108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Brockhaus, R. 1980. Risk taking propensity of entrepreneurs. Academy of Management Journal, 23: 509–520.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Budner, S. 1982. Intolerance of ambiguity as a personality variable. Journal of Personality, 30: 29–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Burt, R. 1992. The social structure of competition. In N. Nohria, & R. Eccles (Eds.), Networks and Organizations. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
  23. Cable, D., & Shane, S. 1997. A prisoner’s dilemma approach to entrepreneur-venture capitalist relationships. Academy of Management Review, 22(1): 142–176.Google Scholar
  24. Casson, M. 1982. The Entrepreneur. Totowa, NJ: Barnes & Noble Books.Google Scholar
  25. Chen, C., Greene, P., & Crick, A. 1998. Does entrepreneurial self-efficacy distinguish entrepreneurs from mangers? Journal of Business Venturing, 13(4): 295–316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Christensen, C. M., & Bower, J. 1996. Customer power, strategic investment, and the failure of leading firms. Strategic Management Journal, 17: 197–218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Cohen, W., Levin, R., & Mowery, D. 1987. Firm size and R&D intensity: A re-examination. Journal of Industrial Economics, 35(4): 543–565.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Cohen, W., & Levinthal, D. A. 1990. Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35: 128–152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Collins, C., Hanges, P., & Locke, E. 2004. The relationship of achievement motivation to entrepreneurial behavior: A Meta-Analysis. Human Performance, 17(1): 95–117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Dixit, A., & Pindyk, R. 1994. Investment Under Uncertainty. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  31. Drucker, P. 1985. Innovation and Entrepreneurship. New York, NY: Harper Business.Google Scholar
  32. Dunne, T., Roberts, M., & Samuelson, L. 1988. Patterns of firm entry and exit in U. S. manufacturing industries. Rand Journal of Economics, 19(4): 495–515.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Evans, D., & Leighton, L. 1989. Some empirical aspects of entrepreneurship. The American Economic Review, 79(3): 519–535.Google Scholar
  34. Gaglio, C. M., & Katz, J. 2001. The psychological basis of opportunity identification: Entrepreneurial alertness. Small Business Economics, 16: 95–111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Gaglio, C. M. & Taub, R. P. 1992. Entrepreneurs and opportunity recognition. In N. C. Churchill, et al. (Eds.), Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research: 136–147. Wellesley, MA: Babson College.Google Scholar
  36. Geroski, P. 2001. Exploring the niche overlaps between organizational ecology and industrial economics. Industrial and Corporate Change, 10(2): 507–540.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Gompers, P. 1999. Ownership and control in entrepreneurial firms: An examination of convertible securities in venture capital: Harvard University.Google Scholar
  38. Gompers, P., & Lerner, J. 1999. The Venture Capital Cycle. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  39. Gordon, L. A. 2004. Managerial Accounting: Concepts and Empirical Evidence. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill, Inc.Google Scholar
  40. Granovetter, M. 1973. The strength of weak ties. American Journal of Sociology, 78: 1360–1380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Gulati, R. 1995. Does familiarity breed trust? The implications of repeated ties for contractual choice in alliances. Academy of Management Journal, 38(1): 85–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Gulati, R., & Gargiulo, M. 1999. Where do interorganizational networks come from? American Journal of Sociology, 105(5): 1439–1494.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Hannan, M., & Freeman, J. 1977. The population ecology of organizations. American Journal of Sociology, 82: 929–964.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Hannan, M., & Freeman, J. 1984. Structural inertia and organizational change. Strategic Management Journal, 14: 59–73.Google Scholar
  45. Harper, D. 1996. Entrepreneurship and the Market Process: An Enquiry Into the Growth of Knowledge. London: Burns & Oates.Google Scholar
  46. Hayek, F. 1945. The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review, 33(4): 519–530.Google Scholar
  47. Henderson, R. 1993. Underinvestment and incompetence as responses to radical innovation: evidence from the photolithographic alignment equipment industry. Rand Journal of Economics, 24(2): 248–268.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Henderson, R., & Clark, K. B. 1990. Architectural innovation: The reconfiguration of existing product technologies and the failure of established firms. Administration Science Quarterly, 27: 548–570.Google Scholar
  49. Highfield, R., & Smiley, R. 1987. New business starts and economic activity. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 5: 51–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Hoffman, H., & Blakely, J. 1987. You can negotiate with venture capitalists. Harvard Business Review, 65(2): 16–24.Google Scholar
  51. Holmstrom, B. 1989. Agency costs and innovation. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 12(3): 305–327.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Johannisson, B. 2000. Networking and entrepreneurial growth. In D. Sexton, & H. Landstrom (Eds.), The Blackwell Handbook of Entrepreneurship. Malden, MA: Blackwell Publishers.Google Scholar
  53. Jovanovic, B. 1982. Selection and the evolution of industry. Econometrica, 50(3): 649–670.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Junkuknc, M., & Eckhardt, J. 2009. Specialized knowledge and owner liquidity in initial public offerings. Management Science, 55(10): 1670–1687.Google Scholar
  55. Kaplan, S., & Strömberg, P. 2003. Financial contracting theory meets the real world: An empirical analysis of venture capital contracts. Review of Economic Studies, 70(2): 281–315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Khilstrom, R., & Laffont, J. 1979. A general equilibrium entrepreneurial theory of firm formation based on risk aversion. Journal of Political Economy, 87(4): 719–748.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. Kirzner, I. 1973. Competition and Entrepreneurship. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  58. Kirzner, I. 1985. Discovery and the Capitalist Process. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  59. Kirzner, I. 1997. Entrepreneurial discovery and the competitive market process: An Austrian approach. Journal of Economic Literature, 35: 60–85.Google Scholar
  60. Klevorick, A., Levin, R., Nelson, R., & Winter, S. 1995. On the sources and significance of interindustry differences in technological opportunities. Research Policy, 25: 185–205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. Knight, F. 1921. Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit. New York, NY: Augustus Kelly.Google Scholar
  62. Larson, A. 1992. Network dyads in entrepreneurial settings: A study of the governance of exchange relationships. Administration Science Quarterly, 37(1): 76–105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Levin, R. C., Klevorick, A., Nelson, R., & Winter, S. 1987. Appropriating the returns from industrial research and development. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 3: 783–831.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. Martin, R. 1988. Franchising and risk management. American Economic Review, 78(5): 954–969.Google Scholar
  65. McClelland, D. 1961. The Achieving Society. New York, NY: Free Press.Google Scholar
  66. Michael, S. 1996. To franchise or not to franchise: An analysis of decision rights and organizational form shares. Journal of Business Venturing, 11: 57–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  67. Miller, D., & Drodge, C. 1986. Psychological and traditional determinants of structure. Administration Science Quarterly, 31: 539–560.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  68. Nelson, R. 1995. Recent evolutionary theorizing about economic change. Journal of Economic Literature, 33(1): 48–90.Google Scholar
  69. Pearce, D. W. (Ed.). 1992. The MIT Dictionary of Modern Economics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  70. Pellmar, T. C., & Eisenberg, L. 2000. Bridging Disciplines in the Brain, Behavioral, and Clinical Sciences. Washington, D. C.: National Academy Press.Google Scholar
  71. Romanelli, E. 1989. Environments and strategies of organization start-up: effects on early survival. Administrative Science Quarterly, 34: 369–387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  72. Ronstadt, R. 1988. The corridor principle. Journal of Business Venturing, 3: 31–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  73. Rosenberg, N. 1976. On technological expectations. The Economic Journal: 523–535.Google Scholar
  74. Rotter, J. 1966. Generalized expectancies for internal versus external control of reinforcement. Psychological Monographs: General and Applied, 80: 609.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  75. Sahlman, W. 1990. The structure and governance of venture capital organizations. Journal of Financial Economics, 27: 473–521.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  76. Sarasvathy, S., Simon, H., & Lave, L. B. 1998. Perceiving and managing business risks: Differences between entrepreneurs and bankers. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 33(2): 207–226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  77. Schmookler, J. 1965. Technological change and economic theory. American Economic Review, 55(1/2): 333–341.Google Scholar
  78. Schumpeter, J. A. 1934. The Theory of Economic Development. New York, NY: Oxford Univ. Press.Google Scholar
  79. Sexton, D. L. & Bowman, 1986. Validation of a Personality Index: Comparative Psychological Characteristics Analysis of Female Entrepreneurs, Managers, Entrepreneurship Students, Business Students. In R. Ronstadt, et al. (Eds.), Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research: 18–28. Wellesley, MA: Babson College.Google Scholar
  80. Shackle, G. 1982. Imagination and the Nature of Choice. Edinburgh, Scotland: Edinburgh University Press.Google Scholar
  81. Shane, S. 1996. Explaining variation in rates of entrepreneurship in the United States: 1899–1988. Journal of Management, 22(5): 747–781.Google Scholar
  82. Shane, S. 1998. Making new franchise systems work. Strategic Management Journal, 19(7): 697–707.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  83. Shane, S. 2000. Prior knowledge and the discovery of entrepreneurial opportunities. Organization Science, 11(4): 448.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  84. Shane, S. 2001a. Technological opportunities and new firm creation. Management Science, 47(2): 205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  85. Shane, S. 2001b. Technology regimes and new firm formation. Management Science, 47(9): 1173–1190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  86. Shane, S. 2008. The Illusions of Entrepreneurship. New Haven, CN: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  87. Shane, S., & Cable, D. 2002. Network ties, reputation, and the financing of new ventures. Management Science, 48(3): 364–381.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  88. Shane, S., & Stuart, T. 2002. Organizational endowments and the performance of university start-ups. Management Science, 48(1): 154–170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  89. Shane, S., & Venkataraman, S. 2000. The promise of entrepreneurship as a field of research. Academy of Management Review, 26(1): 13–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  90. Shankar, V., Carpenter, G., & Krishnamurthi, L. 1999. The advantages of entry in the growth stage of the product life cycle: An empirical analysis. Journal of Marketing Research, 36: 269–276.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  91. Singh, R., Hills, G., Hybels, R., & Lumpkin, G. 1999. Opportunity recognition through social network characteristics of entrepreneurs. In P. Reynolds, W. Bygrave, C. Manigart, C. Mason, G. Meyer, H. J. Sapienza, & K. Shaver (Eds.), Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research: 228–241. Babson Park, Babson, MA: Babson College.Google Scholar
  92. Smith, A. 1776. An Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Edinburgh, Scotland: University of Edinburgh Press.Google Scholar
  93. Spector, P. 1992. Behavior in organizations as a function of locus of control. Psychological Bulletin, 91: 482–497.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  94. Stewart, W. H., & Roth, P. L. 2001. Risk propensity differences between entrepreneurs and managers: A meta-analytic review. Journal of Applied Psychology, 86(1): 145–153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  95. Stigler, G. 1961. The economics of information. The Journal of Political Economy, 69(3): 213–225.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  96. Teece, D. J. 1981. The market for know-how and the efficient international transfer of technology. The Annals of the American Academy, 458: 81–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  97. Teece, D. J. 1987. Technology transfer by multinational firms: The resource cost of transferring technological know-how. Economic Journal, 87: 242–261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  98. Tushman, M., & Anderson, P. 1986. Technological discontinuities and organizational environments. Administration Science Quarterly, 31: 439–465.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  99. Venkataraman, S. 1997. The distinctive domain of entrepreneurship research: An editor’s perspective. In J. Katz, & R. Brockhaus (Eds.), Advances in Entrepreneurship, Firm Emergence and Growth, Vol. 3: 119–138. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.Google Scholar
  100. Von Hippel, E. 1988. The Sources of Innovation. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  101. West, P., & Meyer, G. 1997. Temporal dimensions of opportunistic change in technology-based ventures. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 22(2): 31–52.Google Scholar
  102. Zucker, L., Darby, M., & Armstrong, J. 2002. Commercializing knowledge: University science, knowledge capture, and firm performance in biotechnology. Management Science, 48(1): 138–153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  103. Zucker, L., Darby, M., & Brewer, M. 1998. Intellectual human capital and the birth of U.S. biotechnology enterprises. American Economic Review, 88(1): 290–306.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2010

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of Management and Human Resources, The Weinert Center for EntrepreneurshipUniversity of WisconsinMadisonUSA
  2. 2.Case Western Reserve UniversityClevelandUSA

Personalised recommendations