Advertisement

Industrial Dynamics and Productivity in Morocco: A Quantitative Assessment

  • Lahcen Achy
  • Khalid Sekkat
Chapter

Abstract

Since the early 1980s, the Moroccan authorities have decided to switch from a model of a relatively closed import substitution economy with a large public sector to free trade and a market oriented economy. Price liberalization policy has been one of the main components of the Structural Adjustment program (SAP). Most prices of goods and services were freed in order to promote competition and allow market mechanisms to have a greater role in allocating and pricing factors, goods and services. The country speeded up the process of economic reforms during the 1990s. The new strategy is thought to set the economy on a path of higher efficiency as a result of the intense competition, and thus foster growth and development.

Keywords

Labor Productivity Manufacturing Sector Trade Liberalization Exit Rate Entry Rate 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

References

  1. Achy L (2006) Job creation and job destruction in the manufacturing sector in Morocco. Cahiers du Plan, 8Google Scholar
  2. Achy L, Sekkat K (2008) Competition, efficiency and competition policy in Morocco. In: Khalid Sekkat (ed) Competition and efficiency in the Arab world. Palgrave-McMillan, Basingstoke, Hampshire, pp 123–158Google Scholar
  3. Aw BY, Chung D, Roberts M (2000) Productivity and turnover in the export market: micro-level evidence from the republic of Korea and Taiwan (China). World Bank Econ Rev 14:65–90Google Scholar
  4. Baldwin J (1995) The dynamics of industrial competition. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Bartelsman E, Haltiwanger J, Scarpetta S (2004) Microeconomic evidence of creative destruction in industrial and developing countries. Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper (TI 2004-114/3)Google Scholar
  6. Bernard A, Jensen J (1999) Exporting and productivity, NBER Working Paper No. 7135. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  7. Boeri T, Cramer U (1992) Employment Growth, Incumbents and Entrants: Evidence from Germany. Int J Ind Organ 10:545–565CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Borjas GJ, Ramey VA (1995) Foreign competition, market power, and wage inequality. Q J Econ 110:1075–1110CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Carree M, Thurik A (1999) The carrying capacity and entry and exit flows in retailing. Int J Ind Organ 17:985–1007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Caves RE (1998) Industrial organization and new findings on the turnover and mobility of firms. J Econ Lit 36(8):1947–1982Google Scholar
  11. Churchill B (1955) Age and life expectancy of business firms. Surv Curr Bus 35(12):15–19Google Scholar
  12. Disney R, Haskel J, Heden Y (2003a) Exit entry and establishment survival in UK manufacturing. J Ind Econ 51:93–115Google Scholar
  13. Disney R, Haskel J, Heden Y (2003b) Restructuring and productivity growth in UK manufacturing. Econ J 113(489):666–694CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Fotopoulos G, Spence N (1998) Entry and exit from manufacturing industries: symmetry, turbulence and simultaneity – some empirical evidence from Greek manufacturing industries 1982–1988. Appl Econ 30:245–262CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Geroski P (1995) What do we know about entry. Int J Ind Organ 13:421–441CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Harrison A, Hanson G (1999) Who gains from trade reform? Some remaining puzzles. J Dev Econ 59:125–154CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Hausman R, Rodrik D (2006) Economic development as self-discovery. J Dev Econ 72(2003):603–633Google Scholar
  18. Hoekman B, Winters A (2005) Trade and employment: stylized facts and research findings. ECES Working Paper No. 102 May 2005Google Scholar
  19. Hölzl W, Sögner L (2004) Entry and exit dynamics in Austrian manufacturing. Vienna University of Economics & Business Administration, Working Paper in Growth and Employment in Europe: Sustainability and Competitiveness, No. 36, June 2004Google Scholar
  20. Hulten CR (2000) Total factor productivity: a short biography. NBER working paper 7471Google Scholar
  21. Klapper L, Laeven L, Rajan R (2004) Business environment and firm entry: evidence from international data. NBER Working Paper No. 10380Google Scholar
  22. Mauro P. (1995), “Corruption and Growth”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol 110 n° 3, p.681-712, August.Google Scholar
  23. Pavcnik N (2002) Trade liberalization, exit and productivity improvements: evidence from Chilean plants. Rev Econ Stud 69(1):245–276CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Pricewaterhouse Coopers (2008) Paying taxes: the global picture (joint study with the World Bank)Google Scholar
  25. Revenga A (1997) Employment and wage effects of trade liberalization: the case of Mexican manufacturing. J Labor Econ 15(3):S20–S43 Part 2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Siegfried JJ, Evans LB (1994) Empirical studies of entry and exit: a survey of evidence. Rev Ind Organ 9:121–155CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Wacziarg R, Wallack JS (2004) Trade liberalization and intersectoral labor movements. J Int Econ 64:411–439CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Wei S-J (2000) How taxing is corruption on international investors? Rev Econ Stat 82(1):1–11CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. World Bank (2006) Country economic memorandum. MoroccoGoogle Scholar
  30. World Trade Organization (2003) Trade policy review. MoroccoGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2010

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.INSEARabatMorocco

Personalised recommendations