Divergent Expectations

  • Paul Davis
  • Michael Pagano
  • Robert Schwartz
Conference paper
Part of the Zicklin School of Business Financial Markets Series book series (CUNY)

Abstract

In a piece first published in Latin in 1738, the mathematician and scientist, Daniel Bernoulli wrote, “ …the determination of the value of an item must not be based on its price, but rather on the utility it yields. The price of the item is dependent only on the thing itself and is equal for everyone; the utility, however, is dependent on the particular circumstances of the person making the estimate (1954).” The statement is germane to the topic of this paper if one substitutes “expected return and risk” for “utility,” and “information set” for “the particular circumstances.” This is because an equity’s share price is the same for everyone, but each person forms his or her own expectations about the stock’s future expected return and risk based on a common information set that people may all have.

Keywords

Hepatitis Europe Arena Volatility Monopoly 

References

  1. Anderson, L.R., and C.A. Holt, ‘Classroom Games: Information Cascades,’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 10 (1996), 187–193.Google Scholar
  2. Anderson, L.R., and C.A. Holt, ‘Information Cascades in the Laboratory,’ American Economic Review 87 (1997), 847–862.Google Scholar
  3. Bagehot, W., (pseud), ‘The Only Game in Town,’ Financial Analysts Journal 8 (1971), 31–53.Google Scholar
  4. Ball, S.B., and C.A. Holt, ‘Classroom Games: Speculation and Bubbles in an Asset Market,’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 12 (1998), 207–218.Google Scholar
  5. Bernoulli, D., ‘Exposition of a New Theory on the Measurement of Risk,’ Econometrica 22 (1), 23–36, first published in 1738.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Black, F., ‘Noise,’ Journal of Finance 41 (1986), 529-543.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Chakraborty, A., M.S. Pagano, and R.A. Schwartz, ‘Bookbuilding,’ Working Paper, New York, NY: Baruch College, 2006.Google Scholar
  8. Davis, P., M.S. Pagano, and R.A. Schwartz, ‘Markets in Transition: Looking Back and Peering Forward,’ in W. Bessler, ed., Banken, Borsen und Kapitalmarkte (Banks, Exchanges, and Capital Markets), Berlin: Duncker & Humblot, 2006a.Google Scholar
  9. Davis, P., M.S. Pagano, and R.A. Schwartz, ‘Where are Trades Made in a Fast Market Environment? Life after the Big Board Goes Electronic,’ Financial Analysts Journal 62 (2006b), 14–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Foucault, T., ‘Order Flow Composition and Trading Costs in a Dynamic Order Driven Market,’ Journal of Financial Markets, 2 (1999), 99–134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Grossman, S., and J. Stiglitz, ‘Information and Competitive Systems,’ American Economic Review, 66 (1976), 246–253.Google Scholar
  12. Handa, P., R.A. Schwartz, and A. Tiwari, ‘Quote Setting and Price Formation in an Order Driven Market,’ Journal of Financial Markets, 6 (2003), 461–489.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Milgrom, P., and N. Stokey, ‘Information, Trade, and Common Knowledge,’ Journal of Economic Theory, 26 (1982), 17–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Paroush, J., R.A. Schwartz, and A. Wolf, ‘Stock Price Volatility, Price Discovery, and the Endogeneity of Fundamental Values,’ Working Paper, New York, NY: Baruch College, 2007.Google Scholar
  15. Sarkar, A., and R.A. Schwartz, ‘Two-Sided Markets: Insights into Trading Motives,’ Working Paper, New York, NY: Baruch College, 2007.Google Scholar
  16. Schwartz, R.A., R. Francioni, and B.W. Weber, The Equity Trader Course, New York, NY: Wiley, 2006.Google Scholar
  17. Scheinkman, J., and X. Wei, ‘Overconfidence and Speculative Bubbles,’ Journal of Political Economy, 111 (2003), 1183–1219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2009

Authors and Affiliations

  • Paul Davis
    • 1
  • Michael Pagano
  • Robert Schwartz
  1. 1.TIAA-CREF Investment Management LLCNew YorkUSA

Personalised recommendations