Variety, Spillovers and Market Structure in a Model of Endogenous Technological Change

  • Pietro F. Peretto

Abstract

Growth theorists have produced a number of interesting models investigating the idea that technological progress, the engine of growth in income per capita, is endogenous to the economic system and driven by market forces. These models are radically different from the traditional theory of economic growth based on capital accumulation and emphasize the incentives for profit-seeking agents to undertake R&D aimed at developing new products and processes, or incrementally improving old ones. In particular, infinitely lived and perfectly enforceable patents generate local monopolies by assigning to the innovator the exclusive right to manufacture and sell the new good.1 The emphasis on the non-rivalry of knowledge and the patent law makes clear that imperfect markets and monopoly power are necessary for profit-seeking agents to undertake R&D and innovation. However, these models focus exclusively on monopolistic competition to describe market structure and firms’ behaviour. In addition, the emphasis on the patent market and free entry in R&D neglects the fact that most innovations are carried out by established producers. As a consequence, these models neglect the central role of the oligopolistic corporation and its in-house integration of manufacturing and R&D. Thus, the theory does not address those components of the market structure, like concentration, firm size and market rivalry, emphasized by Schumpeter (1942) as key determinants of the R&D activity of profit-seeking firms.

Keywords

Income Posit Nash Poss Omic 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Aghion, P. and Howitt, P. (1992), ‘A Model of Growth Through Creative Destruction’, Econometrica, 60, 323–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Backus, D., Kehoe, P. and Kehoe, T. (1992), ‘In search of Scale Effects in Trade and Growth’, Journal of Economic Theory, 58, 377–409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Baldwin, W. and Scott, J. (1987), Market Structure and Technological Change (New York: Harwood Academic).Google Scholar
  4. Barro, R. and Sala-i-Martin, X. (1995), Economic Growth (New York: McGraw-Hill).Google Scholar
  5. Beath, J. and Katsoulacos, Y. (1991), The Economic Theory of Product Differentiation (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Chandler, A. (1990), Scale and Scope: the Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
  7. Cohen, W. and Levin, R. (1989), ‘Empirical Studies of Market Structure and Innovation’, in R. Schmalensee and R. Willig (eds), Handbook of Industrial Organization (Amsterdam: North-Holland).Google Scholar
  8. Cohen, W. and Levinthal, D. (1989), ‘Innovation and Learning: The Two Faces of R&D’, Economic Journal, 99, 569–596.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Dasgupta, P. and Stiglitz, J. (1980), ‘Industrial Structure and the Nature of Innovative Activity’, Economic Journal, 90, 266–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Dixit, A. and Stiglitz, J. (1977), ‘Monopolistic Competition and Optimal Product Diversity’, American Economic Review, 67, 297–308.Google Scholar
  11. Dosi, G. (1988), ‘Sources, Procedures, and Microeconomic Effects of Innovation’, Journal of Economic Literature, 36, 1120–71.Google Scholar
  12. Freeman, C. (1982), The Economics of Industrial Innovation (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
  13. Fudenberg, D. and Tirole, J. (1986), Dynamic Models of Oligopoly (New York: Harwood Academy).Google Scholar
  14. Fudenberg, D. and Tirole, J. (1991), Game Theory (Cambridge, MA: MIT University Press).Google Scholar
  15. Grossman, G. and Helpman, E. (1991), Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).Google Scholar
  16. Kamien, M. and Schwartz, A. (1982), Market Structure and Innovation (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
  17. Klevorick, A., Levin, R., Nelson, R. and Winter, S. (1993), ‘On the Sources and Significance of Interindustry Differences in Technological Opportunity’, Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper, 1052 (New Haven: Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale University).Google Scholar
  18. Levin, R., Klevorick, A., Nelson, R. and Winter, S. (1987), ‘Appropriating the Retums from Industrial R&D’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 3, 783–820.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Malerba, F. (1992), ‘Learning by Firms and Incremental Technical Change’, Economic Journal, 102, 845–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Mowery, D. and Rosenberg, N. (1989), Technology and the Pursuit of Economic Growth (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Nelson, R. and Winter, S. (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change (Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
  22. Peretto, P. (1995a), ‘Investment in Knowledge and Capital in Oligopoly: Balanced Growth, Poverty Traps and Indeterminacy’, Duke University (mimeo).Google Scholar
  23. Pereito, P. (1995b), ‘Sunk Costs, Entry, and Endogenous Technological Change’, Duke University (mimeo).Google Scholar
  24. Romer, P. (1986), ‘Increasing Retums and Long-Run Growth’, Journal of Political Economy, 94, 1002–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Romer, P. (1990), ‘Endogenous Technological Change’, Journal of Political Economy, 98, S71–S102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Rosenberg, N. (1976), Perspectives on Technology (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Rosenberg, N. (1982), Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
  28. Scherer, F. and Ross, D. (1990), Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance (Boston: Houghton Mifflin).Google Scholar
  29. Schumpeter, J. (1934), The Theory of Economic Development (New York: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
  30. Schumpeter, J. (1942), Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy (New York: Harper & Row).Google Scholar
  31. Segerstrom, P., Anant, T. and Dinopoulos E. (1990), ‘A Schumpeterian Model of the Product Life Cycle’, American Economic Review, 80, 1077–92.Google Scholar
  32. Spence, M. (1984), ‘Cost Reduction, Competition, and Industry Performance’, Econometrica, 52, 101–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Sutton, J. (1991), Sunk Costs and Market Structure (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).Google Scholar
  34. Tirole, J. (1988), The Theory of Industrial Organization (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Palgrave Macmillan, a division of Macmillan Publishers Limited 1998

Authors and Affiliations

  • Pietro F. Peretto

There are no affiliations available

Personalised recommendations