Democratic Deficit or Deficit of Democracy?: European Integration and Privileged Institutional Position in Domestic Politics

  • Mitchell P. Smith
Part of the St Antony’s Series book series

Abstract

Theorists who have considered the impact of globalization on democracy argue that deepening interdependence of states exacerbates existing problems of large-scale democracy.1 Problems of inadequate state policy capacities, unequal information across groups and between citizens, accountability of policy-makers, popular inclusion and limited control over the agenda are amplified by transnationalization of political institutions. The loss of control over the political agenda by the national demos is particularly marked in systems of transnational federalism.2 This explains the widespread concern with the democratic deficit of the European Union.

Keywords

Europe Expense Arena Defend Alan 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. 1.
    Robert Dahl, ‘A democratic dilemma: System effectiveness versus citizen participation’ Political Science Quarterly, 109: 1, spring 1994, 23–34;CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. and David Held, ‘From City-states to cosmopolitan order’ in David Held (ed), Prospects for Democracy (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1993).Google Scholar
  3. 2.
    See Robert Dahl, Democracy and Its Critics (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1989), p. 198.Google Scholar
  4. 3.
    European Commissioner Leon Brittan makes essentially this point in his discussion of democracy in the EU: ‘... observe the misguided nature of popular dissent: the European Commission, accurately portrayed as “unelected”, is inaccurately accused of interfering, when no legislation can be passed except by ministers from national governments’, Leon Brittain, The Europe We Need (London: Hamish Hamilton, 1994), p. 28.Google Scholar
  5. 4.
    See, for example, Peter Bachrach, The Theory of Democratic Elitism: A Critique (University of London Press, 1969);Google Scholar
  6. Peter Bachrach and Morton Baratz, ‘The two faces of power’, American Political Science Review, 56, 1962, 947–52;CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Steven Lukes, Power: A Radical View (London: Macmillan, 1974).Google Scholar
  8. 5.
    See Alan S. Milward, The European Rescue of the Nation State (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1992);Google Scholar
  9. Dimitris N. Chryssochoou, ‘Democracy and symbiosis in the European Union: Towards a confederal consociation?’ West European Politics, 17, October 1994, 1–14; and Mitchell P. Smith, ‘The Commission made me do it: Policy preferences and domestic political capacities’, paper presented at the Fourth Biennial International conference of the European Community Studies Association, 1995.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. 8.
    See, inter alia, Brigitte Boyce, ‘The democratic deficit and the European Community’, Parliamentary Affairs, 46: 4, October 1993, 458–77;Google Scholar
  11. Shirley Williams, ‘Sovereignty and Accountability in the European Community’, The Political Quarterly, 61: 3, July-September 1990, 299–317;CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. and Karlheinz Neunreither, ‘The democratic deficit of the European Union: Towards closer cooperation between the European Parliament and the national Parliaments’, Government and Opposition, 29: 3, summer 1994, 299–314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. 17.
    Juliet Lodge, ‘Transparency and democratic legitimacy’, Journal of Common Market Studies, 32: 3, September 1994, 343–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. 21.
    Wayne Sandholtz, and John Zysman, ‘1992: Recasting the European bargain’, World Politics, 42, October 1989, 95–128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. 25.
    Gabriel A. Almond and Sidney Verba, The Civic Culture (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1963).Google Scholar
  16. 26.
    See Jeffry A. Frieden, ‘Invested interests: The politics of national economic policies in a world of global finance’, International Organization, 45, autumn 1991, 425–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. 27.
    Geoffrey Garrett and Peter Lange, ‘Political responses to interdependence: What’s ‘left’ for the left?’, International Organization, 45, autumn 1991, pp. 539–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. 28.
    See Ton Notermans, ‘The abdication from national policy autonomy: why the macroeconomic policy regime has become so unfavorable to labor’, Politics & Society, 21, June 1993, 133–67. The author suggests (p. 160) that ‘The ability to pursue growth and full-employment policies has not been eradicated by the anonymous forces of international mobile capital or technological change ...’. Furthermore, ‘the presently dominant views in ... political economy have served to conceal the potential autonomy of present-day societies by invoking what can only be called false necessities’.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. 29.
    Kendall W. Stiles, ‘IMF conditionality: Coercion or compromise?’, World Development, 18 1986, 959–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. 30.
    Paul Mosley, ‘Conditionality as bargaining process: Structural-adjustment lending, 1980–86’, Essays in International Finance, No. 168, October 1987, 9 (International Finance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University).Google Scholar
  21. 31.
    Robert D. Putnam, ‘Diplomacy and domestic politics: The logic of two-level games’, in Double-Edged Diplomacy, eds Peter B. Evans, Harold K. Jacobson and Robert D. Putnam (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993), p. 457.Google Scholar
  22. 32.
    Bruce Wilson, ‘When social democrats choose neoliberal economic policies’, Comparative Politics, 26: 2, January 1994, 149–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. 46.
    Andrew Scott, ‘Industrial policy,’ in Simon Bulmer, Stephen George and Andrew Scott (eds), The United Kingdom and EC Membership Evaluated (New York: St. Martin’s, 1992), p. 74. Also see George Ross, Jacques Delors and European Integration, who points out (p. 57) that one of the tasks of the member of Commission President Jacques Delors’ cabinet responsible for member state aid to industry was ‘not to stir up undue conflict with member states’. One fear was that member states could punish the Commission in other areas of the integration process.Google Scholar
  24. 54.
    Niels Jørgen Nehring, ‘Parliamentary control of the executive’ in Lise Lyck (ed), Denmark and EC Membership Evaluated (New York: St. Martin’s, 1992), p. 79.Google Scholar
  25. 55.
    John Fitzmaurice, ‘National Parliaments and European policy making: The case of Denmark’, Parliamentary Affairs, 29: 3, summer 1976, 286–7. Note that government accountability to the MRC is imperfect, because as Niels Jørgen Nehring, ‘Parliamentary control over the executive’, p. 81, indicates, often there is no concrete proposal to consider for Council of Ministers’ meetings, and decisions on principles may be reached outside the scope of the MRC’s control.Google Scholar
  26. 57.
    Stephen George ‘Central government’, in Simon Bulmer, Stephen George and Andrew Scott (eds), The United Kingdom and EC Membership Evaluated (New York: St. Martin’s, 1992).Google Scholar
  27. 59.
    Carl-Christoph Schweitzer, ‘The effect on the Bundestag’, in Carl-Christoph Schweitzer and Detlev Karsten (eds), The Federal Republic of Germany and EC Membership Evaluated (New York: St. Martin’s, 1990), p. 170, writes that the Bundestag ‘has to a very large extent abdicated in regard to its functions of control and co-decision in favour of its national executive branch in European affairs’. Also see Klaus H. Goetz, ‘National governance and European integration: Intergovernmental relations in Germany’, p. 99.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Palgrave Macmillan, a division of Macmillan Publishers Limited 1997

Authors and Affiliations

  • Mitchell P. Smith
    • 1
  1. 1.Political Science DepartmentMiddlebury CollegeUSA

Personalised recommendations