Vent for Surplus, the Subsistence Fund, and the Evolution of Money

  • P. J. Drake

Abstract

Hla Myint’s 1970 paper contains in its conclusion the important point that the “implicit identification of capital with durable capital goods and complex machinery requires to be seriously qualified when applied to the underdeveloped countries. In the economic setting of these countries the older classical notion of capital as a ‘subsistence fund’ to support labor engaged in producing future output still retains great importance”. Many years earlier, Myint had also observed that “… in Smith’s time, fixed or durable capital played only a very small part in economic life and the bulk of investment was in the form of circulating capital or ‘advances to labour’”1.

Keywords

Rubber Income Smoke Settling Exter 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Caves, R. E. (1965) “‘Vent for Surplus’ Models of Trade and Growth” in R. E. Baldwin and others (eds), Trade, Growth and the Balance of Payments (Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing).Google Scholar
  2. Drake, P. J. (1969) Financial Development in Malaya and Singapore (Canberra: ANU Press).Google Scholar
  3. Drake, P. J. (1972) “Natural Resources Versus Foreign Borrowing in Economic Development”, Economic Journal, March.Google Scholar
  4. Drake, P. J. (1979) “The Economic Development of British Malaya to 1914: An Essay in Historiography with Some Questions for Historians”, Journal of Southeast Asian Studies, September.Google Scholar
  5. Drake, P. J. (1980) Money, Finance and Development (Oxford: Martin Robertson).Google Scholar
  6. Drake, P. J. (1981) “The Evolution of Money in Singapore since 1819” in Monetary Authority of Singapore, Papers on Monetary Economics (Singapore: Singapore University Press).Google Scholar
  7. Finney, Ben (1988) “Culture and Entrepreneurship in the Highlands of Papua New Guinea” in Te’s I. J. Fairbairn (ed.), Island Entrepreneurs: Problems and Performances in the Pacific (Honolulu: East-West Center).Google Scholar
  8. Fisk, E. K. (1962) “Planning in a Primitive Economy: Special Problems of Papua-New Guinea”, Economic Record, December.Google Scholar
  9. Fisk, E. K. (1964) “Planning in a Primitive Economy: From Pure Subsistence to the Production of a Market Surplus”, Economic Record, June.Google Scholar
  10. Huff, W. G. (1989) “Bookkeeping Barter, Money Credit, and Singapore’s International Rice Trade, 1870–1939”, Explorations in Economic History, vol. 26.Google Scholar
  11. Ingham, Barbara (1979) “Vent for Surplus Reconsidered with Ghanaian Evidence”, Journal of Development Studies, April.Google Scholar
  12. Ingham, Barbara (1981) Tropical Exports and Economic Development (London: Macmillan).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Myint, H. (1948) Theories of Welfare Economics (London: Longmans for the London School of Economics and Political Science).Google Scholar
  14. Myint, H. (1954/55) “The Gains from International Trade and the Backward Countries”, Review of Economic Studies, vol. XXII (2).Google Scholar
  15. Myint, H. (1958) “The ‘Classical Theory’ of International Trade and the Underdeveloped Countries”, Economic Journal, June. Reprinted in R. E. Caves and H. G. Johnson (eds.) (1968) Readings in International Economics (Irwin).Google Scholar
  16. Myint, H. (1965) The Economics of the Developing Countries (2nd edn.) (London: Hutchinson).Google Scholar
  17. Myint, H. (1970) “Dualism and the Internal Integration of the Underdeveloped Economies”, Banca Nationale del Lavoro Quarterly Review, June.Google Scholar
  18. Partadireja, Ace. (1974) “Rural Credit: The Ajon System”, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, November.Google Scholar
  19. Schumpeter, J. (1954) History of Economic Analysis (New York: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Gerald M. Meier 1994

Authors and Affiliations

  • P. J. Drake

There are no affiliations available

Personalised recommendations