Abstract
A capital market is said to be efficient if it fully and correctly reflects all relevant information in determining security prices. Formally, the market is said to be efficient with respect to some information set, ϕ, if security prices would be unaffected by revealing that information to all participants. Moreover, efficiency with respect to an information set, ϕ, implies that it is impossible to make economic profits by trading on the basis of ϕ.
Keywords
- Stock Price
- Abnormal Return
- Price Change
- Mutual Fund
- Financial Economic
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.
Buying options
Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout
Purchases are for personal use only
Learn about institutional subscriptionsPreview
Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.
Bibliography
Bachelier, L. 1900. Théorie de la speculation. Annales de l’Ecole normale Supérieure, 3rd series, 17, 21–86. Trans. by A.J. Boness in The Random Character of Stock Market Prices, ed. P.H. Cootner, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1967
Ball, R. 1978. Anomalies in relationships between securities’ yields and yield-surrogates. Journal of Financial Economics 6(2–3), 103–26, June/September, 1981
Banz, R. 1981. The relationship between return and market value of common stocks. Journal of Financial Economics 9(1), March 3–18.
Basu, S. 1977. Investment performance of common stocks in relation to their price earnings ratios: a test of the efficient markets hypothesis. Journal of Finance 32(3), June, 663–82.
Basu, S. 1983. The relationship between earnings’ yield, market value and the return of NYSE common stocks: further evidence. Journal of Financial Economics 12(1), June, 129–56.
Cornell, B. and Roll, R. 1981. Strategies for pairwise competitions in markets and organizations. Bell Journal of Economics 12(1), Spring, 201–13.
Cowles, A. 1933. Can stock market forecasters forecast? Econometrica 1(3), July, 309–24.
Cowles, A. and Jones, H. 1937. Some posteriori probabilities in stock market action. Econometrica 5(3), July, 280–94.
Dodd, P. 1981. The effect on market value of transactions in the market for corporate control, Proceedings of Seminar on the Analysis of Security Prices, CRSP. Chicago: University of Chicago, May.
Fama, E. 1965. The behavior of stock market prices. Journal of Business 38(1), January, 34–105.
Fama, E. and Blume, M. 1966. Filter rules and stock market trading. Security Prices: A Supplement, Journal of Business 39(1), January, 226–41.
Fama, E., Fisher, L., Jensen, M. and Roll, R. 1969. The adjustment of stock prices to new information. International Economic Review 10(1), February, 1–21.
French, K. 1980. Stock returns and the weekend effect. Journal of Financial Economics 8(1), March, 55–69.
Friend, I., Brown, F., Herman, E. and Vickers, D. 1962. A Study of Mutual Funds. Washington, DC: US Government Printing Office.
Granger, D. and Morgenstern, O. 1963. Spectral analysis of New York Stock Market prices. Kyklos 16, January, 1–27.
Grossman, S. and Stiglitz, J. 1980. On the impossibility of informationally efficient markets. American Economic Review 70(3), June, 393–408.
Gultekin, M. and Gultekin, N. 1983. Stock market seasonality, international evidence. Journal of Financial Economics 12(4), December, 469–81.
Jaffé, J. 1974. The effect of regulation changes on insider trading. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 5(1), Spring, 93–121.
Jaffé, J. and Westerfield, R. 1984. The week-end effect in common stock returns: the international evidence. Unpublished manuscript, University of Pennsylvania, December.
Jensen, M. 1969. Risk, the pricing of capital assets, and the evaluation of investment portfolios. Journal of Business 42(2), April, 167–247.
Jensen, M. 1978. Some anomalous evidence regarding market efficiency. Journal of Financial Economics 6(2–3), June-September, 95–101.
Keim, D. 1983. Size related anomalies and stock return seasonality: further empirical evidence. Journal of Financial Economics 12(1), June, 13–32.
Kendall, M. 1953. The analysis of economic time series. Part I: Prices. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society 96(1), 11–25.
Kleidon, A. 1986. Variance bounds, tests and stock price valuation models. Journal of Political Economy 94(5), October, 953–1001.
Kraus, A. and Stoll, H. 1972. Price impacts of block trading on the New York Stock Exchange. Journal of Finance 27(3), June, 569–58.
Malkiel, B. 1980. The Inflation-Beater’s Investment Guide. New York: Norton.
Malkiel, B. 1985. A Random Walk Down Wall Street. 4th edn, New York: Norton.
Mandelbrot, B. 1966. Forecasts of future prices, unbiased markets, and martingale models. Security Prices: A Supplement, Journal of Business 39(1), January, 242–55.
Marsh, T. and Merton, R. 1983. Aggregate dividend behavior and its implications for tests of stock market rationality. Working Paper, Sloan School of Management, September.
Merton, R. 1980. On estimating the expected return on the market: an exploratory investigation. Journal of Financial Economics 8(4), December, 323–61.
Osborne, M. 1959. Brownian motions in the stock market. Operations Research 7(2), March/April, 145–73.
Pearson, K. and Rayleigh, Lord. 1905. The problem of the random walk. Nature 72, 294, 318, 342.
Rendelman, R., Jones, C. and Latané, H. 1982. Empirical anomalies based on unexpected earnings and the importance of risk adjustments. Journal of Financial Economics 10(3), November, 269–87.
Roberts, H. 1959. Stock market ‘patterns’ and financial analysis: methodological suggestions. Journal of Finance 14(1), March, 1–10.
Roberts, H. 1967. Statistical versus clinical prediction of the stock market. Unpublished manuscript, CRSP, Chicago: University of Chicago. May.
Roll, R. 1984. Orange juice and weather. American Economic Review 74(5), December, 861–80.
Samuelson, P. 1965. Proof that properly anticipated prices fluctuate randomly. Industrial Management Review 6(2), Spring, 41–9.
Scholes, M. 1972. The market for securities: substitution versus price pressure and the effects of information on share prices. Journal of Business 45(2), April, 179–211.
Shiller, R.J. 1981. Do stock prices move too much to be justified by subsequent changes in dividends? American Economic Review 71(3), June, 421–36.
Solnik, B. 1973. Note on the validity of the random walk for European stock prices. Journal of Finance 28(5), December, 1151–9.
Thompson, R. 1978. The information content of discounts and premiums on closed-end fund shares. Journal of Financial Economics 6(2–3), June-September, 151–86.
Watts, R. 1978. Systematic ‘abnormal’ returns after quarterly earnings announcements. Journal of Financial Economics 6(2–3), June-September, 127–50.
Working, H. 1934. A random difference series for use in the analysis of time series. Journal of the American Statistical Association 29, March, 11–24.
Editor information
Editors and Affiliations
Copyright information
© 1989 Palgrave Macmillan, a division of Macmillan Publishers Limited
About this chapter
Cite this chapter
Malkiel, B.G. (1989). Efficient Market Hypothesis. In: Eatwell, J., Milgate, M., Newman, P. (eds) Finance. The New Palgrave. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-20213-3_13
Download citation
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-20213-3_13
Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, London
Print ISBN: 978-0-333-49535-3
Online ISBN: 978-1-349-20213-3
eBook Packages: Palgrave Economics & Finance CollectionEconomics and Finance (R0)