Disequilibrium Analysis in Developing Economies: An Overview

  • Bela Balassa

Abstract

Following contributions by Haberler,1 Bhagwati and Ramaswami2 and Johnson,3 Bhagwati4 formulated a general theory of distortions in product and in factor markets. Bhagwati distinguished between ‘endogenous’ and ‘policy-imposed’ distortions, depending on whether departures from optimal resource allocation result from market imperfections or from policy actions.

Keywords

Income Turkey Malaysia Argentina Librium 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. 1.
    G. Haberler, ‘Some Problems in the Pure Theory of International Trade’, Economic Journal, LX (1950) pp. 223–240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. 2.
    J. N. Bhagwati and V. K. Ramaswani, ‘Domestic Distortions, Tariffs, and the Theory of Optimum Subsidy’, Journal of Political Economy, LXXI (1963) pp. 44–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. 3.
    H. G. Johnson, ‘Optimal Trade Intervention in the Presence of Domestic Distortions’, in R. Baldwin et al. (eds), Trade, Growth and the Balance of Payments, Essays in Honor of Gottfried Haberler (Chicago: Rand McNally, 1965) pp. 3–34.Google Scholar
  4. 4.
    J. N. Bhagwati, ‘The Generalized Theory of Distortions and Welfare’, in J. Bhagwati, R. Jones, R. Mundell and J. Vanek (eds), Trade, Balance of Payments and Growth, Papers in International Economics in Honor of Charles P. Kindleberger (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1971) pp. 69–90.Google Scholar
  5. 5.
    S. P. Magee, ‘Factor Market Distortions, Production and Trade: A Survey’, Oxford Economic Papers, XXV (1973) pp. 2–3.Google Scholar
  6. 6.
    S. P. Magee, International Trade and Distortions in Factor Markets (New York: Marcel Dekker, 1976).Google Scholar
  7. 8.
    B. Balassa et al.The Structure of Protection in Developing Countries (Baltimore, Maryland: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1971) p. 72 and Developing Strategies in Semi-Industrial Economies (Baltimore, Maryland: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1982) Ch. 2.Google Scholar
  8. 9.
    B. Balassa, ‘Reforming the System of Incentives in Developing Countries’, World Development, III (1975) pp. 365–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. 10.
    World Bank, Accelerated Development in Sub-Saharan Africa: An Agenda for Action (Washington, DC, 1981).Google Scholar
  10. 12.
    B. Balassa, ‘Incentive Policies in Brazil’, World Development, VII (1979) pp. 1023–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Reprinted in B. Balassa, The Newly Industrializing Countries in the World Economy (New York: Pergamon Press, 1981) pp. 231–54.Google Scholar
  12. 13.
    W. Hong, ‘Export Promotion and Employment Growth in South Korea’, in A. Krueger et al. (eds), Trade and Employment in Developing Countries 1. Individual Studies (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1981) pp. 341–91.Google Scholar
  13. 14.
    R. I. McKinnon, Money and Capital in Economic Development (Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution, 1973).Google Scholar
  14. 15.
    E. S. Shaw, Financial Deepening in Economic Development (New York: Oxford University Press, 1973).Google Scholar
  15. 16.
    These adverse effects are mitigated if unorganized money markets assume the role of financial intermediation. It has been suggested that, in this event, the results will depend on the extent of substitution between time deposits, on the one hand, and unorganized money markets and ‘unproductive’ assets, on the other, as well as on bank reserve requirements and limitations imposed on bank lending (S. van Wijnbergen, ‘Interest Rate Management in LDCs: Theory and Some Simulation Results For South Korea’, Journal of Monetary Economics, XII (1983) pp. 433–52). It should be added, however, that informal credit markets tend to be fragmented; in rural areas, lenders often assume monopolistic positions; and transaction costs are increased by legal limitations on such credit.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. 19.
    S. Guisinger, ‘Trade Policies and Employment: The Case of Pakistan’, in A. O. Krueger et al. (eds), Trade and Employment in Developing Countries 1. Individual Studies (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1981) p. 332.Google Scholar
  17. 28.
    A. C. Harberger, ‘Using the Resources at Hand More Effectively’, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, XLIX (1959) p. 140.Google Scholar
  18. 30.
    B. Balassa, ‘Integración Regional y Asignación de Recursos en America Latina’, Comercio Exterior, XII (1966) pp. 672–85. Moshe Syrquin pointed out to the author that Harberger has subsequently reconsidered his estimate removing the assumption that there would be some domestic production of each importable good in the absence of restrictions and assuming more realistic tariffs. With these modifications, he estimated the cost of protection at 10–15 percent of GNP in Chile.Google Scholar
  19. Cf. A. C. Harberger, Taxation and Welfare (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1974) p. 107.Google Scholar
  20. 31.
    J. Bergsman, Brazil’s Industrialization and Trade Policies (London: Oxford University Press, 1970) Appendix 4.Google Scholar
  21. 32.
    Balassa et al Structure of Protection in Developing Countries, p. 82, Bergsman’s revised estimate — derived by the use of the same methodology — was 7.1 percent for Brazil in 1967, following reductions in the extent of protection below the 1966 level. Cf. J. Bergsman, ‘Commercial Policy, Allocation Efficiency and “X-Efficiency”’. Quarterly Journal of Economics, LXXXVIII (1974) p. 421.Google Scholar
  22. 33.
    A. O. Krueger, ‘Some Economic Costs of Exchange Control: The Turkish Case’, Journal of Political Economy, LXXXIX (1981) pp. 466–80.Google Scholar
  23. 34.
    J. de Melo, ‘Estimating the Costs of Protection: A General Equilibrium Approach’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, CXII (1978) p. 217.Google Scholar
  24. 37.
    H. G. Johnson, ‘The Cost of Protection and the Scientific Tariff’, Journal of Political Economy, LXVIII (1960) pp. 327–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. 38.
    H. G. Johnson, ‘Factor Market Distortions and the Shape of the Transformation Curve’, Econometrica, XXXIV (1966) pp. 686–98. Drawing on Johnson’s results, Nugent estimated the cost of protection for a hypothetical country that cannot affect world market prices in a three-commodity general equilibrium model. Under the assumptions that the three commodities are consumed in equal quantities under free trade, that the elasticity of substitution in consumption is 1, and that the elasticity of substitution in domestic production is 1.5, he found that the cost of protection would rise from 15.6 to 19.6 percent of GNP if importables had tariffs of 30 and 70 percent, rather than a 50 percent tariff on each. The cost of protection would rise further, to 29.8 percent of GNP, if the tariffs on the two importables were 0 and 100 percent, respectively.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Cf. J. B. Nugent, Economic Integration in Central America: Empirical Investigations (Baltimore, Maryland: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1974) p. 66.Google Scholar
  27. 40.
    C. Dougharty and M. Selowsky, ‘Measuring the Effects of the Misallocation of Labor’, Review of Economics and Statistics, LV (1973) p. 389.Google Scholar
  28. 41.
    J. de Melo, ‘Distortions in the Factor Market: Some General Equilibrium Estimates’, Review of Economics and Statistics, LIX (1977) p. 402.Google Scholar
  29. 42.
    M. Syrquin, ‘Efficient Input Frontiers for the Manufacturing Sector in Mexico, 1965–1980’, International Economic Review, XIV (1973) pp. 657–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. 44.
    P. T. Schultz, ‘Effective Protection and the Distribution of Personal Income by Sector in Columbia’ in A. O. Krueger (ed.), Trade and Employment in Developing Countries 2. Factor Supply and Substitution (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1982) pp. 83–148.Google Scholar
  31. 45.
    A. C. Harberger, ‘The Incidence of the Corporation Income Tax’, Journal of Political Economy, LXX (1962) pp. 215–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. 46.
    J. Whalley, ‘A Simulation Experiment into Properties of General Equilibrium Models of Factor Market Distortion’, Review of Economics and Statistics, LIX (1977) p. 200.Google Scholar
  33. 48.
    G. T. Brown, Korean Pricing Policies and Economic Development in the 1960s (Baltimore, Maryland: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1973) pp. 195–7.Google Scholar
  34. 49.
    M. J. Fry, ‘Financial Instruments and Markets’, in Conferencia Internacional Sobre Economia Portuguese (Lisbon: The German Marshall Fund of the United States and Fundacao Calouste Gulbenkian, 1977) p. 196 and ‘The Cost of Financial Repression in Turkey’, Savings and Development, II (1979) p. 132.Google Scholar
  35. 50.
    M. J. Fry, ‘Interest Rates in Asia’, mimeo (Honolulu: University of Hawaii, 1981) Table 9.Google Scholar
  36. 51.
    M. J. Fry, ‘Savings, Investment, Growth and the Terms of Trade in Asia’, Irvine Economic Papers No. 84–7 (1984).Google Scholar
  37. 52.
    International Monetary Fund, Interest Rate Policies in Developing Countries, Occasional Paper No. 22 (Washington, DC, 1983).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. 53.
    F. E. Berger, ‘Thailand: Issues in the Financial Sector’, mimeo (Washington, DC: World Bank, 1982).Google Scholar
  39. 54.
    V. Sundararajan and S. Thakur, ‘Public Investment Crowding Out, and Growth: A Dynamic Model Applied to India and Korea’, International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, XXVII (1980) p. 842.Google Scholar
  40. 60.
    M. J. Fry, ‘Money and Capital in Financial Deepening in Economic Development?’ Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, X (1978) p. 470.Google Scholar
  41. 62.
    H. G. Johnson, ‘The Possibility of Income Losses From Increased Efficiency or Factor Accumulation in the Presence of Tariffs’, Economic Journal, LXXVII (1967) pp. 151–4.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. 63.
    R. Martin, ‘Immiserizing Growth for a Tariff-Distorted Small Economy: A Further Analysis’, Journal of International Economics, VII (1977) pp. 323–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. 65.
    G. Feder, ‘On Exports and Economic Growth’, Journal of Developmental Economics, Vol. XII (1983) pp. 59–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. 67.
    J. de Melo, ‘A Multi-Sector, Price Endogenous Trade Model Applied in Columbia’, Ph.D thesis (Baltimore, Maryland: Johns Hopkins University, 1976) Chapter 8.Google Scholar
  45. 68.
    M. S. Boskin, ‘Taxation, Savings and the Rate of Interest’, Journal of Political Economy, LXXXVI (1978) p. 519.Google Scholar
  46. 69.
    L. H. Summers, ‘Capital Taxation and Assumulation in a Life Cycle Growth Model’, American Economic Review, LXXI (1981) p. 542.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© The World Bank and Bela Balassa 1985

Authors and Affiliations

  • Bela Balassa
    • 1
    • 2
  1. 1.The Johns Hopkins UniversityUSA
  2. 2.The World BankUSA

Personalised recommendations