Skip to main content

Free Trade and the National Economists

  • Chapter
Foreign Trade and the National Economy
  • 41 Accesses

Abstract

Fifty-five years ago John Henry Williams of Harvard University launched a devastating attack on the English classical theory of international trade.1 He criticised the static nature of the theory, the unrealism of its assumptions and its neglect of the interrelations of trade and growth. A theory which assumed fixed quantities of productive factors already existent and fully employed and rules out international factor mobility became merely an exercise in ‘cross-section value analysis’, i.e. a demonstration of static allocative gains. As such it was singularly incapable of dealing with the relation of international trade to ‘the development of new resources and productive forces’ and hence could not offer an explanation for the glaring facts of persistent inequalities of income and structural imbalances among countries. ‘Logically followed through’, said Williams, ‘the classical doctrine of international trade contradicts itself; its conclusions contradict its premises.’2 J. S. Mill was criticised for failure to see (a) ‘the relation of international trade to national economic development spread over time’3 and (b) that specialisation according to comparative advantage was in conflict with the internal mobility assumption. Specialisation for foreign markets freezes the domestic industrial structure and heightens the vulnerability of the economy to external shocks. Smith and, to a lesser extent, Marshall were exempted from this criticism.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes and References

  1. John H. Williams, ‘The Theory of International Trade Reconsidered’, Economic Journal (June 1929) (reprinted in American Economic Association, Readings in the Theory of International Trade ed. H. S. Ellis and L. A. Metzler (Philadelphia: Blakisten, 1949)).

    Google Scholar 

  2. Williams, op. cit. p. 263.

    Google Scholar 

  3. See Gottfried Haberler, ‘International Trade and Economic Development’ — The Cairo Lectures, reprinted in Richard S. Weckstein (ed.) Expansion of World Trade and the Growth of National Economies (New York: Harper & Row, 1968) p. 103.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Williams, op. cit. p. 267.

    Google Scholar 

  5. All are reprinted in J. Robinson, Collected Economic Papers, vols 1–5 (Oxford: Blackwell, 1951–79).

    Google Scholar 

  6. Myrdal’s early critique is contained in his book An International Economy (New York, 1956).

    Google Scholar 

  7. A. Emmanuel, Unequal Exchange: The Imperialism of Trade (London: New Left Books, 1972);

    Google Scholar 

  8. S. Amin, Imperialism and Unequal Development (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1977).

    Google Scholar 

  9. André Gunder Frank, Dependent Accumulation and Underdevelopment (London: Macmillan, 1978).

    Google Scholar 

  10. The expression ‘productive powers’ was used by Hamilton as well as by later French writers such as Jean-Antoine Chaptal, Charles Dupin and Louis Say. List adopted the concept from these French economists and acknowledged his indebtedness, but List’s application of the idea was wider than theirs.

    Google Scholar 

  11. See also George Shelton, Dean Tucker and Eighteenth Century Economic and Political Thought (London: Macmillan, 1981) pp. 126–132, and

    Book  Google Scholar 

  12. J. M. Low, ‘An Eighteenth Century Controversy in the Theory of Economic Progress’, Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies, vol. II, no. 3 (Sep 1952).

    Google Scholar 

  13. Josiah Tucker, Four Tracts together with Two Sermons on Political and Commercial Subjects (Gloucester, 1774) Tract 1, p. 30.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Tucker, Four Tracts, op. cit. p. 28.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Idem, p. 47.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Idem, p. 14.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Idem, p. 49.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Scottish Record Office, Karnes Collection — Tucker to Karnes, 6 July 1758.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Tucker, Four Tracts, op. cit., 3rd ed. (Gloucester, 1776) p. VII. Also British Library Add. MS. 4319, Tucker to Dr Birch, 19 May 1760.

    Google Scholar 

  20. See Samuel McKee Jr (ed.) Papers on Public Credit, Commerce and Finance by Alexander Hamilton (New York: Columbia U.P., 1934).

    Google Scholar 

  21. For analyses of the Report see Joseph Dorfman, The Economic Mind in American Civilization 1606–1865 (New York: Viking Press, 1946) vol. 1, pp. 408–11, and

    Google Scholar 

  22. Louis M. Hacker, Alexander Hamilton in the American Tradition (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1957) pp. 171–83, 132–37, 147–54, 162–4.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Samuel McKee Jr (ed.) Hamilton’s, Papers, op. cit. p. 227.

    Google Scholar 

  24. George C. Fitzpatrick (ed.) The Writings of George Washington (Washington, D.C.: 1931–44) vol. 30, p. 186.

    Google Scholar 

  25. Hamilton’s Papers, pp. 197–8, 228–9.

    Google Scholar 

  26. The Thoughts on Political Economy was the first systematic treatise on economics by an American writer. The Elements was an enlarged second edition of this work.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Raymond, Elements of Political Economy (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins U.P., 1823) vol. II, pp. 225–6, 231–2.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Ibid. pp. 245–6.

    Google Scholar 

  29. For Rae’s writings see the reprint in R. Warren James, John Rae: Political Economist, 2 vols (Toronto: Univ. of Toronto Press, 1965).

    Google Scholar 

  30. For a recent appreciative reassessment of Phillips’s work see James H. Thompson, ‘Willard Phillips: A Neglected American Economist’, History of Political Economy, vol. 16, no. 3 (Fall 1984) pp. 405–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Henry Carey (1793–1879) wrote extensively on economics. His major work (in 3 vols) was Principles of Social Science (Philadelphia, 1858–9).

    Google Scholar 

  32. His protectionist ideas were first developed in Past, Present and Future (1848) and

    Google Scholar 

  33. further elaborated in The Harmony of Interests, Agricultural, Manufacturing and Commercial (Philadelphia, 1851).

    Google Scholar 

  34. Carey, Harmony of Interests, p. 72.

    Google Scholar 

  35. Friedrich List (1789–1846) was born in the town of Reutlingen in Wurttemberg (south Germany) just a few days before the French Revolution broke out. He worked as a civil servant for twelve years in his native state of Württemberg until he was appointed at the age of 28 to a newly created Chair in Public Administration at the University of Tübingen. He was forced to resign his professorship on account of his political activities and involvement with the Hendels- und Gewerbsverein. In 1819 he was elected to the lower chamber of the Württemberg Diet as a representative of Reutlingen. But again, his liberal reforming agitation antagonised the reactionary ruling authorities and List was expelled from the Assembly and sentenced to ten months’ hard labour. This led to his voluntary exile, first in Paris and later in the United States until his return to Germany in 1830 and the continuation of his work on behalf of German economic unity.

    Google Scholar 

  36. See Charles Patrick Neill, Daniel Raymond, an early Chapter in the History of Economic Theory in the United States (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins U.P., 1897) p. 57.

    Google Scholar 

  37. Margaret E. Hirst, Life of Friedrich List (New York, 1909) pp. 114–15.

    Google Scholar 

  38. W. O. Henderson, Friedrich List: Economist and Visionary 1789–1846 (London: Frank Cass, 1983) p. 155.

    Google Scholar 

  39. See William Notz, ‘Friedrich List in America’, American Economic Review, vol. 16, no. 2 (June 1926) pp. 248–65.

    Google Scholar 

  40. See also Edgar Salin and Rene Frey, ‘Triedrich List’ in Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, vol. 9 (New York: Collier-Macmillan, 1968) pp. 409–12, and ch. 1

    Google Scholar 

  41. ‘Economic Nationalism: Friedrich List, Germany’s Handicapped Colbert’ in Louis L. Snyder, Roots of German Nationalism (Bloomington, Ind. U.P., 1978) pp. 1–34.

    Google Scholar 

  42. List, Werke, vol. VI, pp. 153–4.

    Google Scholar 

  43. List, National System, pp. 124–6.

    Google Scholar 

  44. Ibid. pp. 138–9.

    Google Scholar 

  45. Ibid. p. 139 n.

    Google Scholar 

  46. List, Outlines of American Political Economy (1827) in Werke, vol. II p. 105.

    Google Scholar 

  47. List, National System, p. 158.

    Google Scholar 

  48. Ibid, p. X.

    Google Scholar 

  49. List, Outlines (1827) Letter II.

    Google Scholar 

  50. Quoted in K. W. Rowe, Matthew Carey: A Study in American Economic Development (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins U.P., 1933) p. 48.

    Google Scholar 

  51. List, Werke, vol. VI p. 366. List’s discussion at this point and elsewhere suggests the hypothesis that dominant countries would always support an open liberal world-trading system, while laggards would prefer a controlled system. The evidence indicates that this is indeed the case.

    Google Scholar 

  52. List, National System, p. 46.

    Google Scholar 

  53. Ibid. p. 61.

    Google Scholar 

  54. Ibid. p. 61.

    Google Scholar 

  55. S. Sideri, Trade and Power: Informal Colonialism in Anglo-Portuguese Relations (Rotterdam: Rotterdam U.P. 1970) p. 13.

    Google Scholar 

  56. See Charles Gide, Cours d’economie politique (Paris: Sirey, 1931) part II p. 47;

    Google Scholar 

  57. Eduard Heiman, History of Economic Doctrines (London: Oxford U.P., 1945) p. 132;

    Google Scholar 

  58. Rudolph Hilferding, The Economic Policy of Finance Capital edited with an Introduction by Tom Bottomore (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1981) p. 304.

    Google Scholar 

  59. List, National System, p. 75.

    Google Scholar 

  60. Lionel Robbins, The Theory of Economic Development in the History of Economic Thought (London: Macmillan, 1968) p. 116.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  61. E. H. Carr, The Soviet Impact on the Western World (London, 1946) p. 23.

    Google Scholar 

  62. Joan Robinson, Collected Economic Papers (Oxford: Basil Blackwell) vol. V, p. 134.

    Google Scholar 

  63. Myint, Economica op. cit. (Sep 1977).

    Google Scholar 

  64. Collected Economic Papers, vol. I, p. 205.

    Google Scholar 

  65. Lionel Robbins, The Theory of Economic Policy in English Political Economy (London: Macmillan, 1952) p. 10.

    Google Scholar 

  66. List, National System, p. 323.

    Google Scholar 

  67. Ibid. p. 324.

    Google Scholar 

  68. Wealth of Nations (ed.) R. H. Campbell and A. S. Skinner (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1976) p. 539.

    Google Scholar 

  69. List, National System, p. 319.

    Google Scholar 

  70. Ibid. p. 350.

    Google Scholar 

  71. Viner’s review of vol. IV of List’s collected works in Journal of Political Economy (June 1929), reprinted in J. Viner, The Long View and the Short, Studies in Economic Theory and Policy (Glencoe I11.: The Free Press of Glencoe, 1958) pp. 389–91.

    Google Scholar 

  72. A. Anikin, A Science in its Youth (Pre-Marxian Political Economy). (Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1975) p. 334.

    Google Scholar 

  73. ‘List on the Principles of the German Customs Union. Dangers to British Industry and Commerce’, Edinburgh Review no. CLII (July 1842) pp. 521–2.

    Google Scholar 

  74. The Times, 16 Jan 1847, p. 4.

    Google Scholar 

  75. Travers Twiss, View of the Progress of Political Economy Since the 16th Century (London, 1847) p. 248.

    Google Scholar 

  76. Marshall, Principles, 8th ed. (London, 1936) p. 727. Marshall did, in fact, make a special trip to the United States to study the practical effects of the theories of Carey and the other American protectionists.

    Google Scholar 

  77. Schumpeter, History of Economic Analysis, op. cit., p. 504.

    Google Scholar 

  78. Dorfman, op. cit. p. 584.

    Google Scholar 

  79. For an image of List as ‘the only truly cosmopolitan German citizen of his age’ who foresaw and welcomed a united Europe see E. N. Roussakis, Friedrich List, the Zollverein and the Unity of Europe (Bruges, 1968) p. 147.

    Google Scholar 

  80. Kohn was one of the pioneer investigators of nationalism. The remark is contained in his book The Idea of Nationalism (New York, 1944) p. 322.

    Google Scholar 

  81. Snyder, op. cit. p. 34. For an image of List as ‘the only truly cosmopolitan German citizen of his age’ who foresaw and welcomed a united Europe see E. N. Roussakis, Friedrich List, the Zollverein and the Unity of Europe (Bruges, 1968) p. 147.

    Google Scholar 

  82. Gustav Schmoller, in ‘Verhandlungen des Vereins für Sozialpolitik’, Schriften des Vereins für Sozialpolitik (Berlin, 1902) p. 270.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Copyright information

© 1987 Leonard Gomes

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Gomes, L. (1987). Free Trade and the National Economists. In: Foreign Trade and the National Economy. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-08992-5_7

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics