Advertisement

Strategic Retreat on Objectives: Learning from Failure in American Public Policy

  • Aaron Wildavsky

Abstract

How does one group of preferences (say for governmental provision of medical care) succeed another (such as for fees for service by private doctors)? Do people observe what is happening and adjust their preferences accordingly? Preferences, then, would be determined by individual cogitation. Or do people relate to others, modifying their values and beliefs in these engagements? Preferences thus would be a product of social interaction. If preferences result from thinking, our interest should turn to the individual mind; if preferences are molded by interaction, then it is social relations that deserve our attention.

Keywords

Criminal Justice Criminal Justice System Policy Analysis Probation Officer Governmental Provision 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. 1.
    Richard Easterlin says, “Economists have generally insisted that the determination of tastes is not their business.” “Does Economic Growth Improve the Human Lot? Some Empirical Evidence,” in Nations and Households in Economic Growth: Essays in Honor of Moses Abramovitz, Paul E. David and Melvin W. Reder, eds. ( New York: Academic Press, 1974 ), p. 119.Google Scholar
  2. 3.
    See Herbert A. Simon, “On the Concept of Organizational Goal,” Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 9, No. 1 (June 1964), pp. 1–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. See also the “Zone of Indifference” as developed by Chester I. Barnard in his The Functions of the Executive ( Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1968 ).Google Scholar
  4. 4.
    See R. M. Cyert and J. G. March, A Behavioral Theory of the Firm ( Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1963 ).Google Scholar
  5. 5.
    See David Braybrooke and Charles Lindblom, A Strategy of Decision: Policy Evaluation as a Social Process(New York: Free Press, 1963).Google Scholar
  6. 8.
    See Aaron Wildaysky, “Doing Better and Feeling Worse: The Political Pathology of Health Policy,” Daedalus Vol. 106, No. 1 (Winter 1977), pp. 105–123.Google Scholar
  7. 9.
    Title of an essay by Amitai Etzioni in Saturday Review June 3, 1972.Google Scholar
  8. 10.
    See Robert K. Merton, Social Theory and Social Structure ( New York: Free Press, 1957 ).Google Scholar
  9. 11.
    See Mike Preston, “Manpower Politics in California” (Ph.D. dissertation, University of California, Berkeley, June 1974 ).Google Scholar
  10. 12.
    See Mildred Rein, “Work Through Requirements” (draft, May 11, 1978). See also her “Social Services as a Work Strategy,” Social Service Review (December 1975), pp. 515–538.Google Scholar
  11. 14.
    Lesley Oelsner, “Burger Urges New Ways to Resolve Court Disputes,” The New York Times, April 8, 1976, at a meeting of the National Conference on the Causes of Popular Dissatisfaction with the Adiministration of Justice, after a speech with the same title delivered by Dean Roscoe Pound in 1906.Google Scholar
  12. 15.
    Jonathan P. Sher and Rachel B. Tompkins, “Economy, Efficiency and Equality: The Myths of Rural School and District Consolidation” ( Washington, D.C.: National Institute of Education, July 1978 ).Google Scholar
  13. 16.
    See Aaron Wildaysky, “A Bias Toward Federalism,” Publius, Vol. 6, No. 2 (July 1976), pp. 95–120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. 17.
    John Rawls, A Theory of Justice ( Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1971 ).Google Scholar
  15. 18.
    John C. Harsanyi, “Can the Maximin Principle Serve as a Basis for Morality? A Critique of John Rawls’s Theory,” American Political Science Review, Vol. 69, No. 2 (June 1975), pp. 594–606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. 19.
    Guido Calabresi and Grant Gilmore, “Optimal Deterrence and Accidents: To Fleming James Jr.,” Yale Law Journal Vol. 34, No. 4 (March 1975), p. 671.Google Scholar
  17. 20.
    Charles Hersch, “Social History, Mental Health and Community Control,” American Psychologist Vol. 27, No. 8 (August 1972), p. 749.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. 21.
    See Sir Geoffrey Vickers, The Art of Judgment: A Study of Policy Making ( New York: Basic Books, 1965 ).Google Scholar
  19. 22.
    See Judith May, “A Struggle for Authority: A Comparison of Four Social Change Programs in Oakland, California,” (Ph.D. dissertation, University of California, Berkeley, December 1973 ).Google Scholar
  20. 23.
    Charles K. Hitch, “On the Choice of Objectives in Systems Studies” ( Santa Monica: Rand Corporation, 1960 ), p. 19.Google Scholar
  21. 24.
    E. S. Quade, Analysis for Military Decisions ( Chicago: Rand McNally, 1984 ).Google Scholar
  22. 26.
    Horst W. J. Rittel and Melvin Webber, “Dilemmas in a General Theory of Planning,” Policy Sciences, Vol. 4 (1973).Google Scholar
  23. 27.
    J. R. Ravetz, Scientific Knowledge and Its Social Problems ( New York: Oxford University Press, 1971 ), p. 135.Google Scholar
  24. 29.
    Robert K. Merton, “Notes on Problem-Finding in Sociology,” Sociology Today: Problems and Prospects, Robert K. Merton, Leonard Broom, Leonard S. Cottrell, Jr., eds. (New York: Basic Books, 1959), p. v.Google Scholar
  25. 32.
    Frank H. Knight, The Ethics of Competition and Other Essays ( Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1935 ), p. 42.Google Scholar
  26. 34.
    Karl R. Popper, Objective Knowledge: An Evolutionary Approach ( New York: Oxford University Press, 1972 ), pp. 360–361.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Aaron Wildavsky 1979

Authors and Affiliations

  • Aaron Wildavsky

There are no affiliations available

Personalised recommendations