Skip to main content
  • 11 Accesses

Abstract

The classical and neoclassical theories constitute the intellectual backbone of the ‘forced’ strategies. Economists adhering to this impressively consistent body of hypotheses may object to the imputation that their theory has normative implications. At least, the choice of the theory as a strategic device would be considered to be strictly independent from the theory which is understood as being descriptive-explanatory. Such response would faithfully accord with the old tradition (which was brought to a climax in the ‘new welfare economics’) that economics has to describe what is and not to prescribe what should be. By no means is the economist qua economist in a position to make value judgements or to draw policy inferences from his descriptive-explanatory insight. Besides the evident fact that this itself implies a value judgement, the view suggests an ‘objective’ science. It may suffice in the context of this study to stress that the classical and neoclassical theories, once stated, are not without normative implications. By propounding, first, that the body of the classical and neoclassical hypotheses explains European history, and, second, that this experience may be telescoped in Asia, the original descriptive-explanatory theory has normative implications. Clearly, if development is desirable, and the corresponding expectations rely on the blueprint of Western experience, the proposition that a repetition of Western experience is feasible along the lines propounded by classical and neoclassical theory can hardly fail to have strong bearings on policy-making.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 44.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 59.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. For classical contributions see, in particular, W. A. Lewis, ‘Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour’, in The Manchester School, vol. 22, May 1954, reprinted in A. N. Agarwala and S. P. Singh (eds), The Economics of Underdevelopment (London: Oxford University Press, 1971), pp. 400–49;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Gustav Ranis and John C. H. Fei, ‘A Theory of Economic Development’, in American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, Sept. 1961, reprinted in Theodore Morgan and George W. Betz (eds.), Economic Development; (Belmont: Wadsworth, 1970) pp. 89–98; Gustav Ranis and John C. H. Fei, ‘Agrarianism, Dualism, and Economic Development’ in Irma Adelman and Eric Thorbecke (eds.), The Theory and Design of Economic Development, op. cit. pp. 3–43. For neoclassical contributions see, for instance, Dale W. Jorgenson, ‘Testing Alternative Theories of the Development of a Dual Economy’, ibid., pp. 45–60; id, ‘The Role of Agriculture in Economic Development: Classical versus Neoclassical Models of Growth’, in Clifton R. Wharton, Jr. (ed.), Subsistence Agriculture and Economic Development (Chicago: Aldine, 1970), pp. 320–48.

    Google Scholar 

  3. See, particularly, Albert O. Hirschman, The Strategy of Economic Development (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1958).

    Google Scholar 

  4. The theory of pressure as stimulants of development has also been applied to the agricultural sector; for instance, Ester Boserup, The Conditions of Agricultural Growth: The Economics of Agrarian Change Under Population Pressure (London: Allen & Unwin, 1965);

    Google Scholar 

  5. and Yujiro Hayami and Vernon W. Ruttan, Agricultural Development: An International Perspective (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1971), pp. 61–3.

    Google Scholar 

  6. John Maynard Keynes, Economic Consequences of the Peace (1918) pp. 16–17,

    Google Scholar 

  7. quoted in Joan Robinson, Economics, An Awkward Corner (London: Allen & Unwin, 1973) p. 12.

    Google Scholar 

  8. See Alexander Gerschenkron, Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1962) p. 16 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  9. See David S. Landes, ‘Japan and Europe: Contrasts in Industrialisation’, in William W. Lockwood (ed), The State and the Economic Enterprise in Japan (Princeton University Press, 1965) pp. 100 if.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Arthur J. Taylor, Laissez-faire and State Intervention in Nineteenth-century Britain (London: Macmillan, 1972), pp. 60–4.

    Google Scholar 

  11. For a discussion on the British ‘individualistic approach’ see L. J. Zimmerman, Poor Lands, Rich lands: the widening Gap (New York: Random House, 1965) pp. 108–20.

    Google Scholar 

  12. A. Vaidyanathan, Some Aspects of Inequalities in Living Standards in Rural India (New Delhi: Planning Commission, 1971) p. 36 ff. Dandekar and Rath’s survey supports, by and large, the above findings. They report that 10 per cent of India’s rural poor have stayed where they were at the beginning of the 1960s, while the 10 per cent of the urban poor have definitely suffered; see V. M. Dandekar and N. Rath, ‘Poverty in India: Dimensions and Trends’, Economic and Political Weekly, vol. 6, 1971, pp. 39 and 40.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Copyright information

© 1979 K. Dopfer

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Dopfer, K. (1979). In the Theoretical Mainstream. In: The New Political Economy of Development. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-04784-0_15

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics