Skip to main content

Security Market Microstructure: The Analysis of a Non-Frictionless Market

  • Chapter
Handbook of Quantitative Finance and Risk Management

Abstract

The Capital Asset Pricing Model describes a frictionless world characterized by infinite liquidity. In contrast, trading in an actual marketplace is replete with costs, blockages, and other impediments. Equity market microstructure focuses on how orders are handled and turned into trades in the non-frictionless environment. For over three decades, the literature has grown while, concurrently, trading systems around the world have been reengineered. After depicting the frictionless CAPM, we consider the development of microstructure analysis, concentrating on issues germane to market architecture. We then consider the design of one facility, Deutsche Börse’s electronic platform, Xetra. Important insights were gained from the microstructure literature during Xetra’s planning period (1994–1997), and Xetra’s implementation marked a huge step forward for Germany’s equity markets. Nevertheless, academic research and the design of a real world marketplace remain works in progress.

This chapter includes material from Francioni et al. (2008) and from Schwartz (1988), which was reprinted in Schwartz and Francioni (2004).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 869.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 1,099.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    For a recent discussion, see Davis et al. (2007).

  2. 2.

    For a discussion of the Taylor procedure see, for example, R. G. D. Allen, Mathematical Analysis of Economists, London, England: Macmillan, 1960.

  3. 3.

    Two further assumptions are required to obtain Equation (21.3): (1) the third derivative of utility with respect to wealth is small enough to ignore; and (21.2) the squared deviation of the expected rate of return on the risky asset from the risk-free rate is small enough to ignore.

  4. 4.

    Another major issue addressed by the microstructure literature at that time was the impact of information on trading volume and price (Copeland 1976; Beja and Hakansson 1977; Beja and Goldman 1980).

  5. 5.

    For further discussion, see Cohen et al. (1979).

  6. 6.

    A market supported by informational trading only can indeed function if agents trade with each other because their expectations are divergent. When the information that triggers trading is common knowledge, the condition may be thought of as one where agents are agreeing to disagree.

  7. 7.

    Cohen et al. (1981) describe the tradeoff between execution probability and price improvement in the optimal choice between limit and market orders.

  8. 8.

    See Bach and Baruch (2007) for a recent discussion and further references.

  9. 9.

    See Economides and Schwartz (1995) for a description of alternative call market structures.

  10. 10.

    Trading systems differ in their degree of transparency. Pagano and Röell (1996) investigate whether greater transparency enhances market liquidity by reducing the opportunities for taking advantage of uninformed participants.

  11. 11.

    Also see Hasbrouck (1995), Harvey and Huang (1991) and Jones et al. (1994). Further references are provided by Menkveld et al. (2007).

  12. 12.

    Also see Bessler (2006) for discussion and further references.

  13. 13.

    For further discussion and references regarding liquidity see Amihud and Mendelson (1986), Chordia et al. (2000, 2008), Hasbrouck and Seppi (2001), Amihud (2002) and Pastor and Stambaugh (2003).

  14. 14.

    Adaptive valuation behavior refers to individual agents becoming more bullish (bearish) when learning of the relatively bullish (bearish) attitudes of others.

  15. 15.

    Further discussion of market structure development is provided by Harris (2003).

  16. 16.

    FWB also owned the futures and options exchange Deutsche Termine Börse. After the 1997 merger with SOFFEX, DTB became Eurex.

  17. 17.

    For further discussion and descriptions, see Francioni et al. (2008).

  18. 18.

    Appendix B provides details of Xetra’s design.

  19. 19.

    Interestingly, the microstructure literature on call auctions was relatively sparse at that time. For an early discussion, see Handa and Schwartz (1996b).

  20. 20.

    For further discussion, see J. Pratt, “Risk Aversion in the Small and the Large,” Econometrica, January 1964.

References

  • Amihud, Y. 2002. “Illiquidity and stock returns: cross-section and time-series effects.” Journal of Financial Markets 5, 31–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amihud, Y. and H. Mendelson. 1980. “Dealership market: market-making with inventory.” Journal of Financial Economics 8, 31–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amihud, Y. and H. Mendelson. 1986. “Asset pricing and the bid-ask spread.” Journal of Financial Economics 17, 223–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angel, J. 1997. “Tick size, share prices, and stock splits.” Journal of Finance 52, 655–681.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Back, K. and. Baruch. 2007. “Working orders in limit-order markets and floor exchanges.” Journal of Finance 62, 1589–1621.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bagehot, W. (pseudonym). 1971. “The only game in town.” Financial Analysts Journal 27, 12–14, 22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barclay, M., T. Hendershott, and T. McCormick. 2003. “Competition among trading venues: information and trading on electronic communications networks.” Journal of Finance 58, 2637–2666.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beja, A. and M. B. Goldman. 1980. “On the dynamic behavior of prices in disequilibrium.” Journal of Finance 35, 235–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beja, A. and N. H. Hakansson. 1977. “Dynamic market processes and the rewards to up-to-date information.” Journal of Finance 32, 291–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernstein, P. 1987. “Liquidity, stock markets and market makers.” Financial Management 16, 54–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernstein, P. 2007. “The surprising bond between CAPM and the meaning of liquidity.” Journal of Portfolio Management 34, 11–11.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bessembinder, H. 1999. “Trade execution costs on Nasdaq and the NYSE: a post-reform comparison.” The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 34, 387–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bessembinder, H. 2003. “Quote-based competition and trade execution costs in NYSE-listed stocks.” Journal of Financial Economics 70, 385–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bessembinder, H. and H. Kaufman. 1997a. “A comparison of trade execution costs for NYSE and Nasdaq-listed stocks.” The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 32, 287–310.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bessembinder, H. and H. Kaufman. 1997b. “A cross-exchange comparison of execution costs and information flow for NYSE-listed stocks.” Journal of Financial Economics 46, 293–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bessler, W. (Ed.). 2006. Bösen, Banken und Kapitalmärkte, Duncker & Humblot, Berlin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Biais, B., P. Hillion, and C. Spatt. 1995. “An empirical analysis of the limit order book and the order flow in the paris bourse.” Journal of Finance 50, 1655–1689.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biais, B., L. Glosten, and C. Spatt. 2005. “Market microstructure: a survey of microfoundations, empirical results, and policy implications.” Journal of Financial Markets 8, 217–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chordia, T., R. Roll, and A. Subrahmanyam. 2000. “Commonality in liquidity.” Journal of Financial Economics 56, 3–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chordia, T., R. Roll, and A. Subrahmanyam. 2008. “Liquidity and market efficiency.” Journal of Financial Economics 87, 249–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christie, W. and P. Schultz. 1994. “Why do NASDAQ market makers avoid odd-eighth quotes?” Journal of Finance 49, 1813–1840.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christie, W., J. Harris, and P. Schultz. 1994. “Why did NASDAQ market makers stop avoiding odd-eighth quotes?” Journal of Finance 49, 1841–1860.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, K., S. Maier, R. Schwartz, and D. Whitcomb. 1979. “Market makers and the market spread: a review of recent literature.” The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 14, 813–835.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, K., S. Maier, R. Schwartz, and D. Whitcomb. 1981. “Transaction costs, order placement strategy, and existence of the bid-ask spread.” The Journal of Political Economy 89, 287–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Copeland, T. 1976. “A model of asset trading under the assumption of sequential information arrival.” Journal of Finance 31, 1149–1168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Copeland, T. and D. Galai. 1983. “Information effects on the bid-ask spread.” Journal of Finance 38, 1457–1469.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, P., M. Pagano, and R. Schwartz. 2006. “Life after the big board goes electronic.” Financial Analysts Journal 62(5), 14–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, P., M. Pagano, and R. Schwartz. 2007. “Divergent expectation.” Journal of Portfolio Management 34(1), 84–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. 1968. “The cost of transacting.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 82(1), 33–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Domowitz, I. and B. Steil. 1999. “Automation, trading costs, and the structure of the securities trading industry.” Brookings-Wharton Papers on Financial Services, 33–92.

    Google Scholar 

  • Domowitz, I., J. Glen, and A. Madhavan. 2001. “Liquidity, volatility, and equity trading costs across countries and over time.” International Finance 4, 221–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duffie, D., L. Pedersen, and N. Garleanu. 2007. “Valuation in over-the-counter markets.” Review of Financial Studies 20, 1865–1900.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Economides, N. and R. Schwartz. 1995. “Electronic call market trading.” Journal of Portfolio Management 21, 10–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easley, D. and M. O’Hara. 1987. “Price, trade size, and information in securities markets.” Journal of Financial Economics 19, 69–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easley, D. and M. O’Hara. 1991. “Order form and information in securities markets.” Journal of Finance 46, 905–928.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easley, D. and M. O’Hara. 1992. “Time and the process of security price adjustment.” Journal of Finance 47, 577–606.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engle, R. and C. Granger. 1987. “Co-integration and error correction: representation, estimation and testing.” Econometrica 55, 251–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foucault, T. 1999. “Order flow composition and trading costs in a dynamic order driven market.” Journal of Financial Markets 2, 99–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foucault, T., O. Kaden, and E. Kandel. 2005. “The limit order book as a market for liquidity.” Review of Financial Studies 18, 1171–1217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Francioni, R., S. Hazarika, M. Reck and R. A. Schwartz. 2008. “Equity market microstructure: taking stock of what we know.” Journal of Portfolio Management 35, 57–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garman, M. 1976. “Market microstructure.” Journal of Financial Economics 3, 33–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glosten, L. 1994. “Is the electronic open limit order book inevitable?” Journal of Finance 49, 1127–1161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glosten, L. and P. Milgrom. 1985. “Bid, ask, and transaction prices in a specialist market with heterogeneously informed agents.” Journal of Financial Economics 14, 71–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goettler, R., C. Parlour, and U. Rajan. 2005. “Equilibrium in a dynamic limit order market.” Journal of Finance 60, 2149–2192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, S. 1992. “The information role of upstairs and downstairs markets.” Journal of Business 65, 509–529.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, S. and J. Stiglitz. 1980. “On the impossibility of informationally efficient markets.” American Economic Review 70(3), 393–408.

    Google Scholar 

  • Handa, P. and R. Schwartz. 1996a. “Limit order trading.” Journal of Finance 51, 1835–1861.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Handa, P. and R. Schwartz. 1996b. “How best to supply liquidity to a securities market.” Journal of Portfolio Management 22, 44–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Handa, P., R. Schwartz, and A. Tiwari. 2003. “Quote setting and price formation in an order driven market.” Journal of Financial Markets 6, 461–489.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris, L. 1991. “Stock price clustering and discreteness.” Review of Financial Studies 4, 389–415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris, L. 1994. “Minimum price variations, discrete bid-ask spreads, and quotation sizes.” Review of Financial Studies 7, 149–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris, L. 2003. Trading and exchanges: market microstructure for practitioners, Oxford University Press, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harvey, C. and R. Huang. 1991. “Volatility in the foreign currency futures market.” Review of Financial Studies 4, 543–569.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hasbrouck, J. 1991. “Measuring the information content of stock trades.” Journal of Finance 46, 179–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hasbrouck, J. 1993. “Assessing the quality of a security market: a new approach to transaction-cost measurement.” Review of Financial Studies 6(1), 191–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hasbrouck, J. 1995. “One security, many markets: determining the contribution to price discovery.” Journal of Finance 50, 1175–1199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hasbrouck, J. 2007. Empirical market microstructure, Oxford University Press, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hasbrouck, J. and D. Seppi. 2001. “Common factors in prices, order flows and liquidity.” Journal of Financial Economics 59, 383–411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hasbrouck, J. and G. Sofianos. 1993. “The trades of market makers: an empirical analysis of NYSE specialists.” Journal of Finance 48, 1565–1593.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, T. and H. Stoll. 1980. “On dealer markets under competition.” Journal of Finance 35, 259–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, T. and H. Stoll. 1981. “Optimal dealer pricing under transactions and return uncertainty.” Journal of Financial Economics 9, 47–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, T. and H. Stoll. 1983. “The dynamics of dealer markets under competition.” Journal of Finance 38, 1053–1074.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, T. R. Schwartz, and D. Whitcomb. 1985. “The trading decision and market clearing under transaction price uncertainty.” Journal of Finance 40, 21–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, C., G. Kaul, and M. Lipson. 1994. “Information, trading and volatility.” Journal of Financial Economics 36, 127–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keim, D., and A. Madhavan. 1996. “The upstairs market for large-block transactions: analysis and measurement of price effects.” Review of Financial Studies 9, 1–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kyle, A. 1985. “Continuous auctions and insider trading.” Econometrica 53, 1315–1335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Madhavan, A. 2000. “Market microstructure.” Journal of Financial Markets 3, 205–258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Madhavan, A. and M. Cheng. 1997. “In search of liquidity: an analysis of upstairs and downstairs trades.” Review of Financial Studies 10, 175–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mendelson, M., J. Peake, and T. Williams. 1979. “Toward a modern exchange: the Peake-Mendelson-Williams proposal for an electronically assisted auction market,” in Impending changes for securities markets: what role for the exchange?, E. Bloch and R. Schwartz (Eds.). JAI Press, Greenwich, CT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Menkveld, A., S. Koopman, and A. Lucas. 2007. “Modelling around-the-clock price discovery for cross-listed stocks using state space methods.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 25(2), 213–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mildenstein, E., and H. Schleef. 1983. “The optimal pricing policy of a monopolistic marketmaker in the equity market.” Journal of Finance 38, 218–231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P. and N. Stokey. 1982. “Information, trade and common knowledge.” Journal of Economic Theory 26(1), 17–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, E. 1977. “Risk, uncertainty and divergence of opinion.” Journal of Finance 32, 1151–1168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Hara, M. 1997. Market microstructure theory, Basil Blackwell, Cambridge, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ozenbas, D., R. Schwartz, and R. Wood. 2002. “Volatility in U.S. and European equity markets: an assessment of market quality.” International Finance 5(3), 437–461.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pagano, M. and A. Röell. 1996. “Transparency and liquidity: a comparison of auction and dealer markets with informed trading.” Journal of Finance 51, 579–611.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parlour, C. 1998. “Price dynamics in limit order markets.” Review of Financial Studies 11, 789–816.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parlour, C. and D. Seppi. 2008. “Limit order markets: a survey,” Handbook of financial intermediation & banking, A. W. A. Boot and A. V. Thakor (Eds.), Elesevier, Amsterdam.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paroush, J., R. Schwartz, and A. Wolf. 2008. The dynamic process of price discovery in an equity market, Working paper, Baruch College, CUNY.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pástor, L. and R. Stambaugh. 2003. “Liquidity risk and expected stock returns.” Journal of Political Economy 113, 642–685.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porter, D. and D. Weaver. 1998. “Post-trade transparency on Nasdaq’s national market system.” Journal of Financial Economics 50(2), 231–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandas, P. 2001. “Adverse selection and competitive market making: empirical evidence from a limit order market.” Review of Financial Studies 14, 705–734.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, R. 1991. Reshaping the equity markets: a guide for the 1990s, Harper Business, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, R. and R. Francioni. 2004. Equity markets in action, Wiley, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seppi, D. 1990. “Equilibrium block trading and asymmetric information.” Journal of Finance 45, 73–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smidt, S. 1971. “Which road to an efficient stock market: free competition or regulated monopoly?” Financial Analyst Journal, 27, 18–20, 64–69.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. 1964. “Public regulation of the securities markets.” Journal of Business 37, 117–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stoll, H. 1978. “The supply of dealer services in securities markets.” Journal of Finance 33, 1133–1151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stoll, H. 1989. “Inferring the components of the bid-ask spread: theory and empirical tests.” Journal of Finance 44, 115–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tinic, S. 1972. “The economics of liquidity services.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 86(1), 79–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tinic, S. and R. West. 1980. “The securities industry under negotiated brokerage commissions: changes in the structure and performance of New York stock exchange member firms.” Bell Journal of Economics 11, 29–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2010 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Francioni, R., Hazarika, S., Reck, M., Schwartz, R.A. (2010). Security Market Microstructure: The Analysis of a Non-Frictionless Market. In: Lee, CF., Lee, A.C., Lee, J. (eds) Handbook of Quantitative Finance and Risk Management. Springer, Boston, MA. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-0-387-77117-5_21

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics