Advertisement

Regulation, Trade, and Market Power: Agricultural Chemical Markets and Incentives for Biotechnology

  • Vincent H. Smith
Chapter
  • 1.2k Downloads
Part of the Natural Resource Management and Policy book series (NRMP, volume 30)

Abstract

Chemical companies generally support environmental regulatory segregation of Canadian and U.S. agricultural chemical markets, apparently because it enables them to practice third-order price discrimination. This study provides new cross-section evidence that suggests that price discrimination is practiced. We consider the potential implications of chemical market segregation for the innovation and adoption of biotechnologies that are linked to chemical use and chemical prices in the context of a two-sector-two-country model solved as a two-stage game. Biotechnology implications of regulatory harmonization that reintegrates the two chemical markets are then examined.

Key words

price discrimination agricultural chemicals biotechnology 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Carlson, G., J. Deal, K. McEwan, and B. Deen. 1999. “Pesticide Price Differentials Between Canada and the United States—1999.” Unpublished report prepared for the U.S. Department of Agriculture’s Economic Research Service and Agricultural and Agri-Food Canada, Washington, D.C.Google Scholar
  2. Carlson, J.A., and R. Preston McAfee. 1983. “Discrete Equilibrium Price Dispersion.” The Journal of Political Economy 91(3): 480–493.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Clerides, S.F. 2004. “Price Discrimination with Differentiated Products: Definition and Identification.” Economic Inquiry 42(3): 402–414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Dennison, M. 2000. “Hi-Line Fanner Convicted.” The Great Falls Tribune, November 16, p. 1.Google Scholar
  5. Freshwater, D. 2003. “Free Trade, Pesticide Regulation and NAFTA Harmonization.” The Estey Center Journal of International Law and Trade Policy 4(1): 32–57.Google Scholar
  6. McEwan, K., and B. Daley. 1999. “A Review of Agricultural Pesticide Pricing in Canada—1997.” Unpublished research report, Ridgetown College, Ontario, Canada.Google Scholar
  7. McMillan, J., and P. Morgan. 1988. “Price Dispersion, Price Flexibility, and Repeated Purchasing.” The Canadian Journal of Economics 21(4): 883–902.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Salop, S., and G. Stiglitz. 1977. “Bargains and Ripoffs: A Model of Monopolistically Competitive Rice Dispersion.” The Review of Economic Studies 44(3): 493–510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Smith, V.H., and B.K. Goodwin. 1996. “Multiple Peril Crop Insurance, Moral Hazard and Agricultural Chemical Use.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 78(2): 428–438.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Smith, V.H., and J.B. Johnson. 2004. Agricultural Chemical Prices in Canada and the United States: A Case Study of Alberta and Montana. Policy Issues Paper No. 4, Montana Sate University Agricultural Marketing Policy Center.Google Scholar
  11. Sorensen, A. 2000. “Equilibrium Price Dispersion in Retail Markets for Prescription Drugs.” The Journal of Political Economy 108(4): 833–850.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Stigler, G.J. 1961. “The Economics of Information.” The Journal of Political Economy 69(2): 213–225.Google Scholar
  13. Stole, L.A. 2001. “Price Discrimination in Competitive Environments.” Unpublished manuscript, Department of Economics, University of Chicago.Google Scholar
  14. Varian, H. 1989. “Price Discrimination.” In R. Schmalensee and R.D. Willig, eds., The Handbook of Industrial Organization (Vol. I). Cambridge, MA: Elsevier Science Publishers.Google Scholar
  15. Yoshida, Y. 2000. “Third Degree Price Discrimination in Input Markets: Output and Welfare.” The American Economic Review 90(1): 240–246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2006

Authors and Affiliations

  • Vincent H. Smith
    • 1
  1. 1.Montana State UniversityUSA

Personalised recommendations