Creative Destruction in Economics: Nietzsche, Sombart, Schumpeter

  • Hugo Reinert
  • Erik S. Reinert
Part of the The European Heritage in Economics and the Social Sciences book series (EHES, volume 3)

Abstract

This paper argues that the idea of ‘creative destruction’ enters the social sciences by way of Friedrich Nietzsche. The term itself is first used by German economist Werner Sombart, who openly acknowledges the influence of Nietzsche on his own economic theory. The roots of creative destruction are traced back to Indian philosophy, from where the idea entered the German literary and philosophical tradition. Understanding the origins and evolution of this key concept in evolutionary economics helps clarifying the contrasts between today’s standard mainstream economics and the Schumpeterian and evolutionary alternative.

Keywords

Creative destruction Friedrich Nietzsche Werner Sombart Joseph Alois Schumpeter evolutionary economics 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Appel, M. (1992). Werner Sombart. Theoretiker und Historiker des modernen Kapitalismus. Marburg: Metropolis.Google Scholar
  2. Backhaus, J. (editor) (1996). Werner Sombart (1863–1941), Social Scientist. Marburg: Metropolis, 3 vols.Google Scholar
  3. Buchanan, J. (1979). What Should Economists Do? Indianapolis: Liberty Press.Google Scholar
  4. Burckhardt, J. (1979). Reflections on History. Indianapolis: Liberty Classics.Google Scholar
  5. Drechsler, W. (2004). ‘Natural vs. Social Sciences: On Understanding in Economics’, in Reinert E. (editor), Globalization, Economic Development and Inequality. An Alternative Perspective. Cheltenham: Elgar.Google Scholar
  6. Figl, J. (1991). ‘Nietzsche’s Early Encounters with Asian Thought’, in Parkes, G. (editor), Nietzsche and Asian Thought. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  7. Freeman, C. and Louca, F. (2001). As Time Goes By. From the Industrial Revolution to the Information Revolution. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  8. Giddens, A. (1998). The Third Way — the Renewal of Social Democracy. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
  9. Haberler, G. (1950). ‘Joseph Alois Schumpeter, 1883–1950’, in Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. LXIV, No. 3, August 1950, 333–372.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Hegel, G.W.F. (1953). Reason in History — a general introduction to the philosophy of history. New York: The Liberal Arts Press.Google Scholar
  11. Herder, J.G. (1781). Vom Einfluss der Regierung auf die Wissenschaften, und derWissenschaften auf die Regierung, Berlin: Decker.Google Scholar
  12. Herder, J.G. (1790–92). Ideen zur Philosophie der Geschichte der Menschheit. Karlsruhe: Schmieder.Google Scholar
  13. Industry and Innovation, Vol. 9, Nos. 1–2, April–August 2002, Special Issue: Schumpeter’s “Lost” Seventh Chapter, J.A. Mathews, editor.Google Scholar
  14. Justi, J.H.G. von (1762). Vergleichungen der Europäischen mit den Asiatischen und andern vermeintlich Barbarischen Regierungen, in drey Büchern verfasset. Berlin: In Verlag Johann Heinrich Rüdigers.Google Scholar
  15. Kantzenbach, F. (1970). Johann Gottfried Herder. Hamburg: Rowohlt.Google Scholar
  16. Lenger, F. (1994). Werner Sombart (1863–1941) — eine Biographie. Munich: Beck.Google Scholar
  17. Levy, O. (1929). ‘Friedrich Wilhelm Nietzsche’, entry in Encyclopedia Britannica, 14th edition, Vol. 16. London: Encyclopedia Britannica Company.Google Scholar
  18. Lilla, M. (1993). G. B. Vico. The Making of an Anti-Modern. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  19. Nietzsche, F. (1968a). Thus spoke Zarathustra (translated by W. Kaufmann). London: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
  20. Nietzsche, F. (1968b). Twilight of the Idols (translated by R. Hollingdale). London: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
  21. Nietzsche, F. (1994). On the Genealogy of Morality (translated by C. Diethe). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  22. Nietzsche, F. (1995). Unfashionable observations (translated by R. Gray). Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
  23. Nietzsche, F. (2000). Digitale Bibliothek Band 31: Nietzsche. Berlin: Directmedia (CD-ROM).Google Scholar
  24. Noble, D.F. (1997). The Religion of Technology. The Divinity of Man and the Spirit of Invention. New York: Knopf.Google Scholar
  25. Ottmann, H. (1987). Philosophie und Politik bei Nietzsche. Berlin: de Gruyter.Google Scholar
  26. Pareto, V. (1916). Trattato di Sociologia Generale, Florence: G. Barbèra, 2 volumes. (English edition The Mind and Society. New York: Harcourt, Brace and Company, 1935).Google Scholar
  27. Parkes, G. (editor) (1991). Nietzsche and Asian Thought. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  28. Perez, C. (2002). Technological Revolutions and Financial Capital. The Dynamics of Bubbles and Golden Ages. Cheltenham: Elgar.Google Scholar
  29. Perez, C. (Forthcoming 2004). ‘Technological Revolutions, Paradigm Shifts, And Socio-Institutional Change’, in Reinert E. (editor), Globalization, Economic Development and Inequality. An Alternative Perspective. Cheltenham: Elgar.Google Scholar
  30. Peters, H.F. (1977). Zarathustra’s Sister: The Case of Elisabeth and Friedrich Nietzsche. York: Crown Publishers.Google Scholar
  31. Rand, A. (1957). Atlas Shrugged. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
  32. Reinert, E. (1995). ‘Competitiveness and its predecessors — a 500 year cross-national perspective’. In Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, Vol. 6.Google Scholar
  33. Reinert, E. (2000). ‘Karl Bücher and the Geographical Dimensions of Techno-Economic Change’, in Backhaus, Jürgen (editor), Karl Bücher: Theory — History — Anthropology — Non Market Economies. Marburg: Metropolis.Google Scholar
  34. Reinert, E. (2002). ‘Schumpeter in the Context of two Canons of Economic Thought’, in Industry and Innovation, Vol. 6, No. 1.Google Scholar
  35. Reinert, E. (Forthcoming 2004). (editor), Globalization, Economic Development and Inequality. An Alternative Perspective. Cheltenham: Elgar.Google Scholar
  36. Reinert, E. and Daastøl, A. (1997). ‘Exploring the Genesis of Economic Innovations: The religious gestalt-switch and the duty to invent as preconditions for economic growth’, in European Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 4, No. 2/3, 1997, and in Christian Wolff. Gesammelte Werke, Materialien und Dokumente. Hildesheim: Georg Olms Verlag, 1998.Google Scholar
  37. Reinert, E. and Daastøl, A. (Forthcoming 2004). ‘The Other Canon: The History of Renaissance Economics’, in Reinert, E. (editor), Globalization, Economic Development and Inequality. An Alternative Perspective. Cheltenham: Elgar.Google Scholar
  38. Santarelli, E. and Pesciarelli, E. (1990). ‘The Emergence of a Vision: The Development of Schumpeter’s Theory of Entrepreneurship’, in History of Economic Policy, Vol. 22, Winter 1990, No. 4.Google Scholar
  39. Schacht, R. (1994). Nietzsche, Genealogy, Morality. London: University of California Press.Google Scholar
  40. Shionoya, Y. (1997). Schumpeter and the Idea of Social Sciences. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Original edition, Tokyo 1995).Google Scholar
  41. Schumpeter, J.A. (1908). Das Wesen und der Haupteinhalt der Theoretischen Nationalökonomie. Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot.Google Scholar
  42. Schumpeter, J.A. (1912). Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung. Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot.Google Scholar
  43. Schumpeter, J.A. (1914). Epochen der Dogmen-und Methodengeschichte. Tübingen: Mohr.Google Scholar
  44. Schumpeter, J.A. (1939). Business Cycles. New York: McGraw-Hill, 2 volumes.Google Scholar
  45. Schumpeter, J.A. (1942). Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. New York: Harper.Google Scholar
  46. Sokel, W. (1959). The Writer in Extremis. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
  47. Sombart, W. (1913). Krieg und Kapitalismus. Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot.Google Scholar
  48. Sombart, W. (1902/1927). Der moderne Kapitalismus. München & Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot.Google Scholar
  49. Sombart, W. (1915). Händler und Helden. München & Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot.Google Scholar
  50. Sombart, W. (1930). Die drei Nationalökonomien. München & Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot.Google Scholar
  51. Spann, O. (1930). Types of Economic Theory, London: Allen & Unwin, published in the US as The History of Economics, New York: Norton.Google Scholar
  52. Spengler, O. (1939). Decline of the West. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar
  53. Swedberg, R. (1991). Schumpeter. A Biography. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  54. Vico, G. (1984). The New Science. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
  55. Williams, L.L. (2001). Nietzsche’s Mirror: The World as Will to Power. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield.Google Scholar
  56. Wolff, C. (1750). The Real Happiness of a People under A Philosophical King Demonstrated; Not only form the Nature of Things, but form the undoubted Experience of the Chinese under their first Founder Fohi, and his Illustrious Successors, Hoam Ti, and Xin Num. London: Printed for M. Cooper, at the Globe.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2006

Authors and Affiliations

  • Hugo Reinert
    • 1
  • Erik S. Reinert
    • 2
  1. 1.Cambridge UniversityCambridge
  2. 2.The Other Canon FoundationNorway & Tallinn University of TechnologyEstonia

Personalised recommendations