Advertisement

Technology Policy in the Knowledge-Based Economy

  • Patrick Cohendet
  • Frieder Meyer-Krahmer

Keywords

Social Capital Tacit Knowledge Absorptive Capacity External Knowledge Technology Policy 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

3.7 References

  1. Abramowitz M, David P (1996) Technological change, intangible investments and growth in the knowledge-based economy: the US historical experience. In: Foray D and Lundvall B-A (eds.), Employment and growth in the knowledge-based economy. OECD, Paris.Google Scholar
  2. Adler E, Haas P (1992) Conclusion: epistemic communities, world order, and the creation of a reflective research programme. International Organization 46(1): 367–390.Google Scholar
  3. Amesse F, Cohendet P (2001) Technology transfer revisited, in the perspective of the knowledge based economy. Research Policy 30(9): 1459–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Amin A (1999) The Emilian model: institutional challenges. European Planning Studies 7(4): 389–405.Google Scholar
  5. Amin A, Cohendet P (2004) Architectures of knowledge: firms, capabilities and communities Oxford University Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
  6. Arrow K (1962) Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In: The rate and direction of inventive activity. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp. 609–25.Google Scholar
  7. Bessy C, Brousseau E (1998) Technological licensing contracts: features and diversity, International Review of Law and Economics, 18(December): 451–489.Google Scholar
  8. Bowles S, Gintis H (2000) Social capital and community governance. Working Paper 01/01/003, Santa Fe Institute, available at www.santafe.edu/sfi/publications/Working-Papers/01-0l-003.pdfGoogle Scholar
  9. Callon M (1994) Is science a public good? Science Technology and Human Values 19(4): 395–425.Google Scholar
  10. Callon M (1999a) Le réseau comme forme émergente et comme modalité de coordination. In: Callon M, Cohendet P, Curien N, Dalle J-M, Eymard-Duvernay F, Foray, Schenk E, Réseau et Coordination. Economica, Paris, pp 13–64.Google Scholar
  11. Callon M (1999b) The role of lay people in the production and dissemination of scientific knowledge. Science, Technology and Society 4(1): 81–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Callon M, Cohendet P, Curien N, Dalle J-M, Eymard-Duvernay F, Foray D, Schenk E (1999) Réseau et Coordination. Economica, Paris.Google Scholar
  13. Callon M, Lascoumes P, Barthe Y (2001) Agir dans un monde incertain: Essai sur la démocratic technique. Paris: Seuil.Google Scholar
  14. Callon M, Latour B (1991) La science telle qu’elle se fait. Anthologie de la sociologie des sciences de langue anglaise. La Découverte, Paris.Google Scholar
  15. Cassier M (1995) Les contrats de recherche entre l’université et l’industrie. Thèse de doctorat, Ecole des Mines, Paris.Google Scholar
  16. Ciborra C, Andreu R (2002) Knowledge across boundaries: managing knowledge in distributed organizations. In: Choo CW, Bontis N (eds), The strategic management of intellectual capital and organizational knowledge. Oxford University Press, New York, pp. 575–86.Google Scholar
  17. Cohen MD, Burkhart R, Dosi G, Egigi M, Marengo L, Warglien M, Winter S (1996) Routines and other recurring action patterns of organizations: contemporary research issues. Industrial and Corporate Change 5(3): 653–98.Google Scholar
  18. Cohen WH, Levinthal D (1989) Innovation and learning: the two faces of R&D. The Economic Journal 99: 569–596.Google Scholar
  19. Cohen WH, Levinthal D (1990) Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly 35: 128–152CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Cohendet P, Creplet F, Dupouët O (2000) Organizational innovation, communities of practice and epistemic communities: the case of Linux. In: Kirman A, Zimmermann JB (eds.) Economics with heterogeneous interacting agents. Springer, Berlin, pp. 303–326.Google Scholar
  21. Cohendet P, Diani M (2003) L’organisation comme une communautéde communautés: croyances collectives et culture d’entreprise. Revue d’economie politique septembre-octobre: 697–719.Google Scholar
  22. Cohendet P, Meyer-Krahmer F (2001) The theoretical and policy implications of knowledge codification Research Policy 30(9): 1563–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Cook SDN, Brown JS (1999) Bridging epistemologies: the generative dance between organizational knowledge and organizational knowing. Organization Science 10(4): 381–400.Google Scholar
  24. Cowan R, Foray D (1997) The economics of codification and the diffusion of knowledge. Industrial and Corporate Change 9(2): 211–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Cowan R, David P, Foray D (2000) The explicit economics of knowledge codification and tacitness. Industrial and Corporate Change 9(2): 212–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Cowan R, Jonard N (2001) The workings of scientific communities. MERIT-Infonomics Research Memorandum series WP no 2001-031.Google Scholar
  27. Créplet F, Dupouët O, Kern F, Mehmanpazir B, Munier F (2001) Consultants and experts in management creating companies. Research Policy 30: 1517–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. D’Adderio L (2001) Crafting the virtual prototype: how firms integrate knowledge and capabilities across organisation boundaries. Research Policy 30: 1409–24.Google Scholar
  29. Dasgupta P, David PA (1994) Towards a new economics of science. Research Policy 23: 487–521.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. David PA (1992) Knowledge property and the system dynamics of technical change. In: Proceeding of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics, 1992, Washington DC, The World Bank.Google Scholar
  31. David, P A (1995) Standardization policies for network technologies: the flux between freedom and order revisited. In: Hawkins R, Mansell R, Skea J (eds.) Standards, innovation and competitiveness: the politics and economics of standards in natural and technical environments, Edward Elgar, Aldershot, UK, pp: 15–35.Google Scholar
  32. David PA (2000) The digital technology boomerang: new intellectual property rights threaten global ‘Open Science’. Stanford University, WP no 00-016, October 2000.Google Scholar
  33. David PA (2001) Digital technologies, research collaborations and the extension of protection for intellectual property in science: will building ‘Good Fences’ really make ‘Good Neighbours’?; STRATA-ETAN Workshop.Google Scholar
  34. David PA, Foray D (1995) Accessing and expanding the science and technology knowledge base. STI Review, no16, OECD, Paris: 13–68.Google Scholar
  35. David P, Foray D (1996) Information distribution and the growth of economically valuable knowledge: a rationale for technological infrastructure policies. In: Teubal M, Foray D, Justman M, Zuscovitch E (eds.) Technological infrastructure policy: an international perspective. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht and London, pp. 87–116.Google Scholar
  36. Dosi G (1988) The nature of the innovative process. In: Dosi G, Freeman C, Nelson RR, Silverberg G, Soete L (eds.). Technical change and economic theory. Pinter, London, pp. 221–238.Google Scholar
  37. Foray D (2002) Intellectual property and innovation in the knowledge-based economy. Isuma, 3(1): 1–12, available at: www.isuma.net.Google Scholar
  38. Foss N (1998) Firm and coordination of knowledge: some Austrian insights. Working Paper, DRUID, Copenhagen Business School.Google Scholar
  39. Foss N (1999) Understanding leadership: a coordination theory. Working Paper DRUID, Copenhagen Business School.Google Scholar
  40. Gibbons M, Limoges C, Nowotny H, Schwartzman S, Scott P, Trow M (1994) The new production of knowledge. Sage, London.Google Scholar
  41. Hicks D (1995) Published papers, tacit competencies and corporate management of the public/private character of knowledge. Industrial and Corporate Change 4(2): 401–24.Google Scholar
  42. Joly PB (1997) Chercheurs et laboratoires dans la nouvelle économie de la science. Revue d’Économie Industrielle 79: 77–94.Google Scholar
  43. Joly PB, Mangematin V (1996) Profile of public laboratories, industrial partnerships and organization of R&D. Research Policy 25: 900–22.Google Scholar
  44. Knorr-Cetina K (1981) The manufacture of Knowledge. Pergamon Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
  45. Knorr-Cetina K (1999) Epistemic cultures: how the sciences make sense. Chicago University Press, Chicago.Google Scholar
  46. Kogut B (2000) The network as knowledge: generative rules and the emergence of structure. Strategic Management Journal 21(March): 405–25.Google Scholar
  47. Kogut B, Zander U (1992) Knowledge of the firm, combinative capabilities, and the replication of technology. Organization Science 3: 383–97.Google Scholar
  48. Kogut B, Zander U (1996) What firms do? Coordination, identity and learning. Organization Science 7: 502–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Kremer M (1997) Patents buy-outs. A mechanism for encouraging innovation. NBER Working Paper no. 6304.Google Scholar
  50. Latour, B (1986a) Visualization and cognition: thinking with eyes and hands. Knowledge and Society 6: 1–40.Google Scholar
  51. Latour, B (1986b) Science in action: how to follow scientists and engineers through society, Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA.Google Scholar
  52. Lave J (1988) Cognition in Practice. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
  53. Lissoni F (2001) Knowledge codification and the geography of innovation: the case of Brescia mechanical cluster. Research Policy 30(9): 1479–1550.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Meyer-Krahmer F (1997) Public research/industry linkages revisited. In: Barré R, Gibbons M, Maddox J, Martin B, Papon P (eds.) Science in tomorrow’s Europe. Economica International, Paris, pp. 153–73.Google Scholar
  55. Milgrom P, Roberts J (1988) Economic theories of the firm: past, present, future. Canadian Journal of Economics 21: 444–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Muller E, Zenker A (2001) Business services as actors of knowledge: the role of KIBS in regional and national innovation systems. Research Policy 30: 1501–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. Nelson RR (1959) The simple economics of basic scientific research. Journal of Political Economy 67: 297–306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Nelson RR, Winter S (1982) An evolutionary view of economic change. Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA.Google Scholar
  59. Nonaka I, Takeuchi H (1995) The knowledge-creating company: how the Japanese companies create the dynamic of innovation. Oxford University Press, New York.Google Scholar
  60. Nowotny H, Scott P, Gibbons M (2001) Re-Thinking Science. Polity Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
  61. OECD (2000) Knowledge management in the learning economy: education and skills. Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development, Paris.Google Scholar
  62. Orlean A (ed.) (1994) Analyse économique des conventions. Presses Universitaires de France, Paris.Google Scholar
  63. Pavitt K (1984) Sectoral patterns of technological change: towards a taxonomy and theory. Research Policy 13(6): 343–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. Polanyi M (1958) Personal knowledge. Routledge and Kegan Paul, LondonGoogle Scholar
  65. Prahalad CK, Hamel G (1990) The core competence of the corporation, Harvard Business Review 68(May/June): 79–91.Google Scholar
  66. Rabeharisoa V, Callon M (2002) The involvement of patients in research activities supported by the French Muscular Dystrophy Association. In: Jasanoff S (ed.) States of knowledge: science, power and political culture. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.Google Scholar
  67. Romer P (1993) Implementing a national technology strategy with self-organizing industry boards. Brookings Papers Microeconomics. 2: 345–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  68. Saxenian A (1996) Regional advantage: culture and competition in Silicon Valley and Route 128. Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA.Google Scholar
  69. Schumpeter J (1942) Capitalism, socialism and democracy. Harper, New York.Google Scholar
  70. Stephan P, Levin S (1997) The critical importance of careers in collaborative scientific research. Revue d’économie industrielle 79: 45–61.Google Scholar
  71. Von Hippel E (1993) Trading in trade secrets. Harvard Business Review March/April: 56–64.Google Scholar
  72. Wenger E (1998) Communities of practice: learning as a social system. Systems Thinker.Google Scholar
  73. Wenger E (1998) Communities of practice: learning, meaning, and identity. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
  74. Wenger E, Mcdermott W, Snyder M (2002) Cultivating communities of practice. Harvard Business School Press, Boston.Google Scholar
  75. Wenger E, Snyder WM (2000) Communities of practice: the organizational frontier. Harvard Business Review Jan–Feb: 139–45.Google Scholar
  76. Zuscovitch E (1998) Networks, specialization and trust. In: Cohendet P, Llerena P, Stahn H, Umbhauer G (eds.) The economics of networks. Springer Verlag, Berlin, pp. 243–64.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2005

Authors and Affiliations

  • Patrick Cohendet
    • 1
    • 2
  • Frieder Meyer-Krahmer
    • 1
    • 3
  1. 1.BETAStrasbourg
  2. 2.HECMontréal
  3. 3.FhG-ISIKarlsruhe

Personalised recommendations