Skip to main content

Social Rationality versus Rational Egoism

  • Chapter
Book cover Handbook of Sociological Theory

Part of the book series: Handbooks of Sociology and Social Research ((HSSR))

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  • Alchian, A. A., & Allen, W. R. (1974). University economics, 3rd edition. London: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bargh, J. A. (1984). Automatic and conscious processing of social information. In R. S. Wyer, Jr. & T. K. Srull (Eds.), Handbook of social cognition (pp. 1–44). Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bargh, J. A. (1997). The automaticity of everyday life. In R. S. Wyer (Ed.), The authomaticity of everyday life. Advances in social cognition 10, (pp. 1–61). Mahwah, NJ: Erlbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1996). Accounting for tastes. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berry, D. C., & Dienes, Z. (1993). Implicit learning. Hove, England: Erlbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Binmore, K. (1994). Game theory and the social contract. Volume I: Playing Fair.Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bodenhousen, G. V., & Macrae, C. N. (1998). Stereotype activation and inhibition. In R. S. Wyer (Ed.). Stereotype activation and inhibition. Advances in social cognition 11 (pp. 1–52). Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boudon, R. (1996). The cognitivist model: A generalized rational-choice model. Rationality and Society, 8, 123–150.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G. (1990). What might rationality fail to do? In K. S. Cook & M. Levy (Eds.). The limits of rationality (pp. 51–59). Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Callon, M. (1998). Introduction: The embeddedness of economic markets in economics. In M. Callon (Ed.). The law of the markets (pp. 1–57). Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carnevale, P. J. D., & Lawler, E. J. (1986). Time pressure and the development of integrative agreements in bilateral negotiations. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 30, 636–659.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. S. (1986). Collective decisions. In Individual interests and collective action (pp. 15–32). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. S. (1990). Foundation of social theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Durkheim, E. (1950). The rules of sociological method. Glencoe, IL: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Durkheim, E. (1951). Suicide. A study in sociology. Glencoe, IL: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (1991). Rationality and social norms. Europäisches Archief für Soziologie, 32, 109–129.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (1999). Alchemies of the mind. Rationality and the emotions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Etzioni, A. (1988). The moral dimension. Toward a new economics. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Favereau, O. (1997). L’incomplétue n’est pas le probléme, c’est la solution. In B. Reynaud (Ed.). Les limites de la rationalité. Tome 2, Les Figures du collectief (pp. 219–234). Colloque de Cerisy, Paris: La Decouverte.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fazio, R. H. (1990). Multiple processes by which attitudes guide behavior: The mode model as an integrative framework. Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, 23, 75–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Festinger, L. (1954). A theory of social comparison processes. Human Relations, 7, 117–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. (1990). Rethinking rational choice. In R. Friedland & A. F. Robertson (Eds.). Beyond the marketplace (pp. 53–87). New York: Aldine de Gruyter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. (1992). Frames of reference and the intertemporal wage profile. In G. Loewenstein & J. Elster (Eds.). Choice over time (pp. 371–382). New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S. (1997). Not just for the money. An economic theory of personal motivation. Brookfield: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frisch, D. (1993). Reasons for framing effects. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 54, 399–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gattig, A. (2001). Intertemporal decision making. Amsterdam: Thela Thesis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gollwitzer, P. M., & Moskowitz, G. B. (1996). Goal effects on action and cognition. In E. T. Higgins & A. W. Kruglanski (Eds.). Social psychology. Handbook of basic principles (pp. 361–399). London: Guilford Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goode, W. (1978). The celebration of heroes. Prestige as a control system. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Green, D. P., & Shaprio, I. (1994). Pathologies of rational choice theory. A critique of applications in political science. New Haven, CT, and London: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harsanyi, J. C. (1977a). Rational behavior and bargaining equilibrium in games and social situations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harsanyi, J. C. (1977b). Advances in understanding rational behavior. In R. E. Butts & J. Hintikka (Eds.). Foundational problems in the special sciences (pp. 315–343). Dordrecht: Reidel Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hebb, D. O. (1958). A textbook of psychology. Philadelphia: W. B. Saunders.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helson, H. (1964). Adaptation level theory. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Higgins, E. T., & Brendl, M. (1995). Accessibility and applicability: Some activation rules influencing judgment. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 31, 218–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A. O. (1977). The passions and the interests: Political arguments for capitalism before its triumph. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Houghton, G., & Tipper, S. P. (1996). Inhibitory mechanisms of neural and cognitive control: applications to selective attention and sequential action. Brain and Cognition, 30, 20–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure, Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47, 263–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. H. (1991). Anomalies: the endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5, 193–206.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirchgässner, G. (1992). Towards a theory of low-cost decisions. European Journal of Political Economy, 8, 305–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knight, E (1921). Risk, uncertainty and profit. Chicago: University of Chicago Press (reissue 1971).

    Google Scholar 

  • Krech, D., Crutchfield, R. S., & Ballanchey, E. L. (1962). Individual in society. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kruglanksi, A. W. (1996). Motivated social cognition: Principles of the interface. In E. T. Higgins & A. W. Kruglanski (Eds.). Social psychology. Handbook of basic principles (pp. 493–520). London: Guilford Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levi, M., Cook, K. S., O’Brian, J. O., & Faye, H. (1990). Introduction: The limits of rationality. In K. S. Cook & M. Levi (Eds.). The limits of rationality (pp. 1–18). Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liebrand, W. B. G., Jansen, R. W. T. L., Rijken, V. M., & Suhre, C. J. M. (1986). Might over morality: social values and the perception of other players in experimental games. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 22, 203–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ligthart, P. A. M. (1995). Solidarity in economic transactions: An experimental study of framing effects in bargaining and contracting. Amsterdam: Thela Thesis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ligthart, P. A. M., & Lindenberg, S. (1994). Solidarity and gain maximization in economic transactions: Framing effects on selling prices. In A. Lewis & K. E. Wärneryd (Eds.). Ethics and economic affairs (pp. 215–230). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindenberg, S. (1983). Utility and morality, Kyklos, 36(3), 450–468.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindenberg, S. (1986). The paradox of privatization in consumption. In Diekmann A. & Mitter P. (Eds.). Paradoxical effects of social behavior Essays in honor of Anatol Rapoport (pp. 297–310). Heidelberg/Wien: Physica-Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindenberg, S. (1989a). Choice and culture: The behavioral basis of cultural impact on transactions. In H. Haferkamp (Ed.). Social structure and culture (pp. 175–200). Berlin: de Gruyter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindenberg, S. (1989b). Social production functions, deficits, and social revolutions: pre-revolutionary France and Russia. Rationality and Society, 1(1), 51–77.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindenberg, S. (1990). Homo socio-oeconomicus: The emergence of a general model of man in the social sciences, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 146, 727–748.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindenberg, S. (1991). Social approval, fertility and female labour market behaviour. In J. Siegers, J. de Jong-Gierveld, & E. van Imhoff (Eds.). Female labour market behaviour and fertility: A rational choice approach (pp. 32–58). Berlin/New York: Springer Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindenberg, S. (1992a). An extended theory of institutions and contractual discipline. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 148(2), 125–154.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindenberg, S. (1992b). The method of decreasing abstraction. In J. S. Coleman & T. J. Fararo (Eds.). Rational choice theory: Advocacy and critique (pp. 3–20). Newbury Park, CA: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindenberg, S. (1993). Framing, empirical evidence, and applications. In: Jahrbuch für Neue Politische Okonomie (pp. 11–38).Tübingen: Mohr (Siebeck).

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindenberg, S. (1996). Low evidence situations in the social and historical sciences: Rational choice as a heuristic device. The Netherlands’ Journal of Social Sciences, 32(1), 25–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindenberg, S. (2000). It takes both trust and lack of mistrust: The workings of solidarity and relational signaling in contractual relationships. Journal of Management and Governance, 4, 11–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindenberg, S., & Frey, B. (1993). Alternatives, frames, and relative prices: A broader view of rational choice. Acta Sociologica, 36, 191–205.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, G. F. (1996). Out of control: Visceral influences on behavior. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 65(3), 272–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, G. F, & Elster, J. (Eds.) (1992). Choice over time. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein G. E, & Thaler, R. (1989). Anomalies: Intertemporal choice. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3, 181–193.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mandler, G. (1984). Mind and body: Psychology of emotions and stress. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. (1920). Principles of economics, 8th ed. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meckling, W. (1976). Values and the choice of the model of the individual in the social sciences. Schweizerische Zeitschrift für Volkswirtschaft und Statistik, 112, 545–559.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. (1957). Social theory and social structure. Glencoe, IL: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Millar, M. G., & Tesser, A. (1989). The effects of affective-cognitive consistency and thought on the attitude-behavior relation. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 25, 189–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myers, M. L. (1983). The soul of modern economic man. Ideas of self-interest. Thomas Hobbes to Adam Smith. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1981). Structure and change in economic history. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ormel, J., Lindenberg, S., Steverink, N., & Verbrugge, L. M. (1999) Subjective well-being and social production functions. Social Indicator Research, 46, 61–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parfit, D. (1984). Reasons and persons. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parsons, T. (1937). The structure of social action. Glencoe, IL: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parsons, T., & Shils, E. (1951) Values, motives and systems of action. In T. Parsons & E. Shils (Eds.), Toward a general theory of action (pp. 47–275. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raub W., & Weesie J. (2000). The management of matches: A research program on solidarity in durable relations. Netherlands’ Journal of Social Sciences, 36, 71–88.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reber, A. S. (1993). Implicit learning and tacit knowledge. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, S. (1974). Hedonic prices and implicit markets. Journal of Political Economy, 82, 34–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Russell, J. A. (1983). Pancultural aspects of the human conceptual organization of emotions. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 45, 1281–1288.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scheff, T. J. (1967). Towards a sociological model of consensus. American Sociological Review, 32, 32–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schüßler, R. (1988). Der Homo Oeconomicus als skeptische Fiktion. Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie, 40, 447–463.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scitovsky, T. (1976). The joyless economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sherif, M. (1966). In common predicament: Social psychology of intergroup conflict and cooperation. Boston: Houghton-Mifflin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. (1997). Rationality in psychology and economics. In Models of bounded rationality. Vol. III: Empirically grounded economic reason (pp. 367–385). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1976). The theory of moral sentiments. Glasgow Edition, Vol. I. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. (1965). Essays in the history of economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G., & Becker, G. S. (1977). De gustibus non est disputandum. The American Economic Review, 67, 76–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stinchcombe, A. (1986). Reason and rationality. Sociological Theory, 4(2), 151–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turner, J. C. (1991). Social influence. Pacific Grove, CA: Brooks/Cole Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turner J. H. (2000). On the origins of human emotions. A sociological inquiry into the evolution of human affect. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vallacher, R. R., & Wegner, D. M. (1987). What do people think they are doing? Action identification and human behavior. Psychological Review, 94, 3–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Bruggen, A. (2001). Individual production of social well-being. Groningen; Dissertation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Varese, F, & Yaish M. (2000). The importance of being asked: The rescue of Jews in Nazi Europe. Rationality and Society, 12, 307–334.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watson, D., & Tellegen, A. (1985). Toward a consensual structure of mood. Psychological Bulletin, 98, 219–235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1961). Genearl economic history. New York: Collier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1993). Calculativeness, trust, and economic organization. Journal of Law and Economics, XXXVI, 453–486.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wippler, R. (1990). Cultural resources and participation in high culture. In M. Hechter, K.-D. Opp, & R. Wippler (Eds.). Social institutions. Their emergence, maintenance, and effects (pp. 187–204). New York: Aldine de Gruyter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wittek, R. (2000). Governance by reorganization. Research proposal, Groningen: ICS/University of Groningen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wright, R. (1994). The moral animal. Why we are the way we are: The new science of evolutionary psychology. New York: Vintage Books.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2001 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Lindenberg, S. (2001). Social Rationality versus Rational Egoism. In: Turner, J.H. (eds) Handbook of Sociological Theory. Handbooks of Sociology and Social Research. Springer, Boston, MA . https://doi.org/10.1007/0-387-36274-6_29

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/0-387-36274-6_29

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Boston, MA

  • Print ISBN: 978-0-387-32458-6

  • Online ISBN: 978-0-387-36274-8

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics