Advertisement

Time Zone Differences and Service Trade

  • Biswajit Mandal
  • Alaka Shree PrasadEmail author
Chapter

Abstract

The paper explains how service trade has been facilitated because of the availability and development of Information and Communication Technology (ICT). With this, the paper points to the emerging theory of time zone (TZ) differences and trade where time zone difference between two countries evokes service trade given the availability of ICT. A simple 2 × 2 general equilibrium framework is considered to explain the effect of trade across non-overlapping time zones on factor prices and output. Results show a rise in the wage of skilled labour and a fall in rent. The result is conditional on the assumptions of factor intensity. In the case of output, the sector exploiting the time zone difference is seen to expand while the other contracts. This outcome, however, is independent of the assumption of factor intensity.

Keywords

Time zones Outsourcing Services Trade 

JEL Classification

F1 F11 

References

  1. Afonso, P., Nunes, M., Paisana, A., & Braga, A. (2008). The influence of time-to-market and target costing in the new product development success. International Journal of Production Economics, 115(2), 559–568.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2008.07.003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Carmel, E., Espinosa, J. A., & Dubinsky, Y. (2010). “Follow the sun” workflow in global software development. Journal of Management Information Systems, 27(1), 17–38.  https://doi.org/10.2753/MIS0742-1222270102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Christen, E. (2017). Time zones matter: The impact of distance and time zones on services trade. The World Economy, 40(3), 612–631.  https://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Deardorff, A. (2003). Time and trade: The role of time in determining the structure and effects of international trade, with an application to Japan. In R. M. Stern (Ed.), Japans economic recovery: Commercial policy, monetary policy and corporate governance (pp. 63–76). UK: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.Google Scholar
  5. Dettmer, B. (2014). International service transactions: Is time a trade barrier in a connected world? International Economic Journal, 28(2).  https://doi.org/10.1080/10168737.2013.825305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Fernandez-Stark, K., Bamber, P., & Gereffi, G. (2011). The offshore services global value chain: Economic upgrading and workforce development. Duke University, Center on Globalization, Governance and Competitiveness. Retrieved from https://gvcc.duke.edu/wp-content/uploads/2011-11-11_CGGC_Ex.Summary_Offshore-Services-Global-Value-Chain-1.pdf.
  7. Gupta, A. (2007). Deriving mutual benefits from offshore outsourcing: The 24-hour knowledge factory scenario. SSRN Electronic Journal.  https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.968761.
  8. Gupta, A., & Seshasai, S. (2007). 24-hour knowledge factory: Using internet technology to leverage spatial and temporal separations. ACM Transactions on Internet Technology, 7(3), 14.  https://doi.org/10.1145/1275505.1275507.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Head, K., Mayer, T., & Ries, J. (2009). How remote is the offshoring threat? European Economic Review, 53(4), 429–444.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2008.08.001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Hummels, D., & Schaur, G. (2013). Time as a trade barrier. The American Economic Review, 103(7), 2935–2959.  https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.103.7.2935.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Jones, R. W. (1965). The structure of simple general equilibrium models. The Journal of Political Economy, 73(6), 557–572. Retrieved from http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28196512%2973%3A6%3C557%3ATSOSGE%3E2.0.CO%3B2-B.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Jones, R. W. (1971). A three-factor model in theory, trade and history. In J. Bhagwati, R. W. Jones, R. A. Mundell, & J. Vanek (Eds.), Trade, balance of payments and growth (pp. 3–21). North-Holland: Amsterdam.Google Scholar
  13. Kikuchi, T. (2006). Time zones, outsourcing and patterns of international trade. Economics Bulletin, 6, 1–10. Retrieved from http://www.accessecon.com/pubs/EB/2006/Volume6/EB-06F10018A.pdf.
  14. Kikuchi, T., & Iwasa, K. (2010). A simple model of service trade with time zone differences. International Review of Economics and Finance, 19(1), 75–80.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2009.02.004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Kikuchi, T., & Long, N. V. (2011). Shift working and trade in labor services with time zone differences. Pacific Economic Review, 16(5), 553–564.  https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0106.2011.00564.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Kikuchi, T., & Marjit, S. (2010). Time zones and periodic intra-industry trade. (EERI Research Paper Series 08/2010), Economics and Econometrics Research Institute. Retrieved from http://hdl.handle.net/10419/142570.
  17. Kikuchi, T., & Marjit, S. (2011). Growth with time zone differences. Economic Modelling, 28(1–2), 637–640.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2010.06.006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Kikuchi, T., Marjit, S., & Mandal, B. (2013). Trade with time zone differences: Factor market implications. Review of Development Economics, 17(4), 699–711.  https://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12060.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Mandal, B. (2015). Distance, production, virtual trade and growth: A note. Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal, 9(2015–1), 1–12. Retrieved from http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/journalarticles/2015-1.
  20. Mandal, B., Marjit, S., & Nakanishi, N. (2018). Outsourcing, factor prices and skill formation in countries with non-overlapping time zones. Eurasian Economic Review.  https://doi.org/10.1007/s40822-017-0086-9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Marjit, S. (2007). Trade theory and the role of time zones. International Review of Economics and Finance, 16(2), 153–160.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2005.08.002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Marjit, S., & Mandal, B. (2017). Virtual trade between separated time zones and growth. International Journal of Economic Theory, 13(2), 171–183.  https://doi.org/10.1111/ijet.12123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Matsuoka, Y., & Fukushima, M. (2010). Time zones, shift working and international outsourcing. International Review of Economics and Finance, 19(4), 769–778.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2010.05.001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. OECD. (2017). OECD digital economy outlook 2017. Paris: OECD Publishing.  https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264276284-en.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Sooraj, P., & Mohapatra, P. K. J. (2008). Modeling the 24-h software development process. Strategic Outsourcing: An International Journal, 1(2), 122–141.  https://doi.org/10.1108/17538290810897147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Reserve Bank of India. (2018). Survey on computer software & information technology enabled services exports. Retrieved April 30, 2018, from https://rbi.org.in/Scripts/BS_PressReleaseDisplay.aspx.
  27. Taweel, A., & Brereton, P. (2006). Modelling software development across time zones. Information and Software Technology, 48(1), 1–11.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.infsof.2004.02.006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Tomasik, R. (2013). Time zone-related continuity and synchronization effects on bilateral trade flows. Review of World Economics, 149, 321–342.  https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-013-0147-4.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. UNCTAD. (2015). International trade in ICT services and ICT-enabled services: Proposed indicators from the partnership on measuring ICT for development. United Nations. https://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/tn_unctad_ict4d03_en.pdf.
  30. World Trade Organization. (2019). WTO Data. Retrieved January 22, 2019, from http://data.wto.org/.

Copyright information

© Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd. 2020

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of Economics & PoliticsVisva-Bharati UniversitySantiniketanIndia

Personalised recommendations