Advertisement

On the Lead–Lag Relationship Between Market Capitalization Ratio and Per Capita Growth

  • Agnirup Sarkar
  • Abhirup SarkarEmail author
Chapter

Abstract

The paper looks at the short-to-medium term lead–lag relationship between stock market performance, as represented by market capitalization to GDP ratio and the performance of the real economy, as represented by per capita GDP growth. The lead–lag relationship is first established theoretically in an asset pricing framework with production and accumulation and then empirically by separately looking at lagged correlations, Granger causality and variance decomposition using data from 35 countries over the period 1988–2012.

Keywords

Growth Market capitalization 

References

  1. Abel, A. B. (1988, October). Stock prices under time varying dividend risk: An exact solution in an infinite horizon general equilibrium model. Journal of Monetary Economics. (Elsevier Science Publishers B.V., North-Holland).Google Scholar
  2. Apergis, N., Artikis, P., & Kyriazis, D. (2015). Does stock market liquidity explain real economic activity? New evidence from two large European stock markets. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 38, 42–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Aylward, A., & Glen, J. (2000). Some international evidence on stock prices as leading indicators of economic activity. Applied Financial Economics, 10, 1–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Beck, T., Demirguc-Kunt, A., & Levine, R. (2000). A new database on the structure and development of the financial sector. World Bank Economic Review, 14(3), 597–605.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Bencivenga, V. R., & Smith, B. D. (1991). Financial intermediation and endogenous growth. The Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 195–209.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Bencivenga, V. R., Smith, B. D., & Starr, R. M. (1995). Equity markets, transaction costs and capital accumulation. Policy Research Working Paper Series 1456, The World Bank.Google Scholar
  7. Brock, W. A. (1982). Asset prices in a production economy, UMI. In J. McCall (Ed.), The economics of information and uncertainty (pp. 1–46).Google Scholar
  8. Brock, W. A., & Mirman, L. J. (1972). Optimal economic growth and uncertainty: The discounted case. Journal of Economic Theory, 4, 479–513.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Chen, Y., Eaton, G., & Paye, B. (2018). Micro (structure) before macro? The predictive power of aggregate illiquidity for stock returns and economic activity. Journal of Financial Economics, 130(1), 48–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Choi, J., Hauser, S., & Kopecky, K. (1999). Does stock market predict real economic activity? Time series from G7 countries. Journal of Banking and Finance, 23, 1771–1792.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Cochrane, J. H. (1991). Production-based asset pricing and the link between stock returns and economic fluctuations. The Journal of Finance, 46(1), 209–237.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Estrella, A., & Hardouvelis, G. (1991). The term structure as a predictor of real economic activity. The Journal of Finance, XLVI(2), 555–576.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Fama, E. F. (1965). The behaviour of stock market prices. The Journal of Business, 38(1), 34–105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Fase, M. M. G., & Abma, R. C. N. (2003). Financial development and economic growth in selected Asian countries. Journal of Asian Economics, 14(2003), 11–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Goldsmith, R. W. (1969). Financial structure and development. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  16. Gorton, G., & Pennacchi, G. (1990). Financial intermediaries and liquidity creation. Journal of Finance, 45(1), 49–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Greenwood, J., & Jovanovic, B. (1990). Financial development, growth and the distribution of income. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5(1)), 1076–1107.Google Scholar
  18. Hicks, J. (1969). A theory of economic history. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
  19. Jacklin, C. J. (1987). Demand deposits, trading restrictions, and risk sharing. In E. Prescott & N. Wallace (Eds.), Contractual arrangements for international trade (pp. 26–47). Minneapolis, MN: University of Minnesota Press.Google Scholar
  20. Japelli, T., & Pagano, M. (1994). Saving, growth, and liquidity constraints. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109(1), 83–109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. King, R. G., & Levine, R. (1993a). Financial intermediation and economic development. In C. Mayer & X. Vives (Eds.), Financial intermediation in the construction of Europe (pp. 156–89). London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.Google Scholar
  22. King, R. G., & Levine, R. (1993b). Finance and growth: Schumpeter might be right. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(3), 717–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. King, R. G., & Levine, R. (1993c). Finance entrepreneurship and growth: Theory and evidence. Journal of Monetary Economics, 32(3), 513–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Levanon, G., Manini, J., Ozyildrim, A., & Schaitkin, B. (2015). Using financial indicators to predict turning points in business cycle: The case of the leading economic index for the United States. International Journal of Forecasting, 31(2), 426–445.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Levine, R. (1991). Stock markets, growth and tax policy. The Journal of Finance, 46(4), 1445–1465.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Levine, R., & Zervos, S. (1996). Stock market development and long run growth. The World Bank Economic Review, 10(3), 323–339.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Ljungqvist, L., & Sargent, T. (2004). Recursive macroeconomic theory (2nd ed.). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  28. Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1978, November). Asset prices in an exchange economy. Econometrica, 46(6), 1429–1445.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Mills, L. (1988). Can stock prices reliably predict recessions? Business Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, 1–12.Google Scholar
  30. Rajan, R. G., & Zingales, L. (1998). Financial systems, industrial structure and growth. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 17(4), 467–482.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Reinhart, C., & Rogoff, K. (2009). The aftermath of financial crisis. American Economic Review, 99(2), 466–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Sarkar, A., & Sarkar, A. (2019). Do stock markets signal real economic performance? A theoretical and empirical note. In S. Sikdar (Ed.), Forthcoming in a Conference Volume of IIM Calcutta.Google Scholar
  33. Schumpeter, J. A. (1934) [1912]. The theory of economic development (R. Opie, Trans.). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd. 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Indian Institute of Technology GuwahatiGuwahatiIndia
  2. 2.Indian Statistical Institute KolkataKolkataIndia

Personalised recommendations