Advertisement

The Theory of Public Goods

Chapter
  • 1.5k Downloads
Part of the Springer Texts in Business and Economics book series (STBE)

Abstract

In Chap.  8, we investigated taxation from the viewpoint of efficiency. In this chapter, we investigate government spending from the viewpoint of efficiency. Here, the notion of public goods is important. As explained in Chap.  1, public goods have properties of non-rivalness and non-excludability. Non-rivalness in consumption means that an increase in someone’s consumption does not reduce the availability of consumption for others. Non-excludability means that someone cannot be excluded from consuming a good because of technical or other reasons simply because she or he does not pay the price.

Keywords

Public goods Non-rivalness Non-excludability Pure public goods Impure public goods Club goods, commons Samuelson rule Nash equilibrium approach Private provision of public goods Lindahl equilibrium Person-specific burden ratio Free rider problem Clarke tax Neutrality theorem of public goods 

References

  1. Andreoni, J. (1990). Impure altruism and donations to public goods: A theory of warm-glow giving. Economic Journal, 100, 464–477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Andreoni, J. (1993). An experimental test of the public-goods crowding-out hypothesis. American Economic Review, 83, 1317–1327.Google Scholar
  3. Batina, R. G., & Ihori, T. (2005). Public goods: Theories and evidence. Berlin/New York: Springer.Google Scholar
  4. Bhagwati, T. L. (1958). Immiserizing growth: A geometrical note. Review of Economic Studies, 25, 201–205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Clarke, E. H. (1971). Multipart pricing of public goods. Public Choice, 11, 17–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Cornes, R., & Rubbelke, D. (2012). On the private provision of contentious public characteristics (ANU working papers in economics and econometrics 577). München: CESifo.Google Scholar
  7. Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1985). Easy riders, joint production and public goods. Economic Journal, 94, 580–598.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1996). The theory of externalities, public goods, and club goods. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  9. Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (2000). Pareto-improving redistribution and pure public goods. German Economic Review, 1, 1690186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Green, J., & Laffont, J.-J. (1979). Incentives in public decision-making. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
  11. Ihori, T. (1994). Immiserizing growth with interregional externalities of public goods. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 24, 485–496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Ihori, T. (1996). International public goods and contribution productivity differentials. Journal of Public Economics, 61, 567–585.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Itaya, J., de Meza, D., & Myles, G. D. (1997). In praise of inequality: Public good provision and income distribution. Economics Letters, 57, 289–296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Lindahl, E. (1919). Just taxation – A positive solution. In R. A. Musgrave & A. T. Peacock (Eds.), Classics in the theory of public finance. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  15. Samuelson, P. A. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. Review of Economics and Statistics, 36, 387–389.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Sandler, T. (1992). Collective action: The theory and application. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
  17. Shibata, H. (2003). Voluntary control of public bad is independent of the aggregate wealth: The second neutrality theorem. Public Finance/Finances Publiques, 53, 269–284.Google Scholar
  18. Warr, P. (1983). The private provision of a public good is independent of the distribution of income. Economics Letters, 13, 207–211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media Singapore 2017

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.National Gradual Institute for Policy StudiesMinato-kuJapan

Personalised recommendations