Militärökonomie pp 1-21 | Cite as
Einführung: Die ökonomische Problematik des Militärs
Quia parvus error in principio magnus est in fine
Chapter
Zusammenfassung
Die heutigen militärischen Organisationen sind keine privaten Unternehmungen, sondern Teil der modernen Nationalstaaten und daher in deren bürokratische Verwaltung integriert. In ökonomischer Hinsicht werden sie daher nach planwirtschaftlichen Grundsätzen geführt. Ignoriert die ökonomische Analyse dieses fundamentale Problem, so erzeugt sie nicht nur falsche Schlussfolgerungen, sondern auch irrelevante Handlungsempfehlungen.
Preview
Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.
Literatur
- Acemoglu D, Robinson J (2012) Why nations fail. Crown, New YorkGoogle Scholar
- Acemoglu D, Johnson S, Robinson J (2001) The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review 91:1369–1401CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Alptekin A, Levine P (2012) Military expenditure and economic growth: A meta-analysis. European Journal of Political Economy 28:636–650CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Arkes J, Cunha JM (2015) Workplace goals and output quality: evidence from time-constrained recruiting goals in the US navy. Defence and Peace Economics 26:491-515CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Baldwin D (1997) The concept of security. Review of Economic Studies 23: 5-26CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Barney JB (1992) Integrating organizational behavior and strategy formulation research: A resource based analysis. In: Shrivastava P, Huff A, Dutton J (eds.), Advances in Strategic Management. JAI Press, Greenwich, CT, 8:39-62Google Scholar
- Bates RH, Grief A, Levi M, Rosenthal JL, Weingast BR (1998) Analytic narratives. Princeton University Press, Princeton NJ.Google Scholar
- Bator FM (1958) The anatomy of market failure. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 72(3):351-379CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Beeres R, Bogers M (2012) Ranking the performance of European armed forces. Defence and Peace Economics 23:1-16CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Bellais R, Foucault M, Oudot JM (2014) Économie de la défense. La Découverte, ParisGoogle Scholar
- Billyard AP, Donohue JJ (2016) A practical organizational efficiency measure. Defence and Peace Economics 27:794-819CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Blagden D (2009) Strategic thinking for the age of austerity. The RUSI Journal 154:60-66CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Blanken LJ, Lepore JJ (2015) Performance measurement in military operations: information versus incentives. Defence and Peace Economics 26:516-535CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Bodin J (1993) Les six livres de la République. Librairie générale française, ParisGoogle Scholar
- Boettke PJ, Coyne C, Leeson P (2013) Comparative historical political economy. Journal of Institutional Economics 9:285–301CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Boettke PJ, Storr V (2002) Post-classical political economy: Polity, society, and economy. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 61:161–191CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Boettke P, Fink A (2011) Institutions first. Journal of Institutional Economics 7(4): 499-504CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Boog H, Förster J, Hoffmann J, Klink E, Müller RD, Ueberschär GR (1985) Das Deutsche Reich und der Zweite Weltkrieg, Band 4: Der Angriff auf die Sowjetunion. Deutsche Verlags-Anstalt, StuttgartGoogle Scholar
- Buchanan JM (1968) The demand and supply of public goods. ChicagoGoogle Scholar
- Buchanan JM (2004) The status of the status quo. Constitutional Political Economy 15:133-144CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Bundesamt für Statistik (2013) Nichtfinanzieller Nettokapitalstock, Methodenbericht. Bundesamt für Statistik, NeuchâtelGoogle Scholar
- Bundesamt für Statistik (2016) Nichtfinanzieller Nettokapitalstock (geometrische Methode). Elektronische Daten. Bundesamt für Statistik, NeuchâtelGoogle Scholar
- Caruso R (2010) Butter, guns and ice-cream: Theory and evidence from sub-Saharan Africa. Defence and Peace Economics 21(3):269-283CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Chardigny C (2013) Contrats et marchés publics de défense. PrimentoGoogle Scholar
- Chen PF, Lee CC, Chiu YB (2014) The nexus between defense expenditure and economic growth: New global evidence. Economic Modelling 36:474–483CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Cowen T (1985) Public good definitions and their institutional context: A critique of public goods theory. Review of Social Economy 43(1): 53-63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Coyne CJ (2015) Lobotomizing the defense brain. The Review of Austrian Economics 28: 371-396CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Coyne CJ, Hall AH (2014) Perfecting tyranny: Foreign intervention as experimentation in social control. The Independent Review 19: 1-25Google Scholar
- Coyne CJ, Mathers RL (eds.) (2011) The handbook on the political economy of war. Edward Elgar, CheltenhamGoogle Scholar
- Davis DM (2011) Designing a viable prediction market to forecast defense acquisition cost and schedule outcomes. Defence and Peace Economics 22:351-366CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Dikici E (2015) Guns versus butter tradeoff: The theory of defense quality factor. Journal of Economics, Business and Management 3:704-709CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Djankov S, Glaeser E, La Porta R, Lopez-de-Silanes F, Shleifer A (2003) The new comparative economics. Journal of Comparative Economics 31:595–619CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Dorobek S (2013) Public supply chain management. Springer Fachmedien, WiesbadenCrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Dosi G, Teece D, Winter S (1990) Les frontières des entreprises: vers une théorie de la cohérence de la grande entreprise. Revue d’économie industrielle 51:238-254CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Doucouliagos C, Stanley TD, Giles M (2012) Are estimates of the value of a statistical life exaggerated? Journal of Health Economics 31:197-206CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Driessnack J, King D (2004) An initial look at technology and institutions on defense industry consolidation. Acquisition Review Journal 35:63-77Google Scholar
- Engerer H (2011) Security as a public, private or club good: Some fundamental considerations. Defense and Peace Economics 22:135-145CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Felin T, Foss NJ, Heimeriks KH, Madsen TL (2012) Microfoundations of routines and capabilities: Individuals, processes, and structure. Journal of Management Studies 49:1351-1374CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Firth R (2013) Elements of social organisation. Routledge, LondonGoogle Scholar
- Forte F (2010) Principles of public economics: A public choice approach. Edward Elgar, CheltenhamGoogle Scholar
- Friedman D (1973) The machinery of freedom: Guide to radical capitalism. Harper and Row, New YorkGoogle Scholar
- Friedman M (1953) Comments on monetary policy. In: Essays in positive economics. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 263-276Google Scholar
- Furubotn EG, Richter R (2005) Institutions and economic theory: The contribution of the new institutional economics. University of Michigan PressGoogle Scholar
- Gimbel J (1986) U.S. Policy and German scientists: The early cold war. Political Science Quarterly 101(3):433-451CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Gimbel J (1990) Science, technology, and reparations: Exploitation and plunder in postwar Germany. Stanford University PressGoogle Scholar
- Greif A (2006) Institutions and the path to the modern economy. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
- Grössl L, Hahn O, Koerdt H (1973) Wirtschaftlichkeit in Streitkräften. Betriebswirtschaftlicher Verlag Dr. Th. Gabler, WiesbadenCrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Hahn O (1997) Militärbetriebslehre: Betriebswirtschaftslehre der Streitkräfte. Berlin-Verlag, BerlinGoogle Scholar
- Hall R (1993) A framework linking intangible resources and capabilities to sustainable competitive advantage. Strategic Management Journal 14:607-618CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Hardin R (1982) Collective Action. Johns Hopkins University Press, BaltimoreGoogle Scholar
- Harrison WR (1975) National Defense as a collective good”. In Craig L, Loehr W, McCamant J (Eds.) Comparative public policy: Issues, theories, and methods. John Wiley and Sons, New York, 199–221Google Scholar
- Hartley K (1995) Industrial policies in the defense sector. In Hartley K, Sandler T (1995) Handbook of defense economics. Amsterdam et al., Elsevier, 459-489Google Scholar
- Hartley K (1997) Defense markets. Economic Affairs 17:22-27CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Hartley K, Sandler T (Eds.) (1995) Handbook of defense economics. Elsevier, AmsterdamGoogle Scholar
- Hayek FA (1944) Der Weg zur Knechtschaft. Mohr Siebeck, TübingenGoogle Scholar
- Hayek FA (1979) Law, legislation and liberty. Chicago University Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
- Head JG, Shoup CS (1969) Public goods, private goods, and ambiguous goods. The Economic Journal 79:567-572CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Hefendehl R, von Hirsch A, Wohlers W (2003) Die Rechtsgutstheorie: Legitimationsbasis des Strafrechts oder dogmatisches Glasperlenspiel? Nomos, Baden-BadenGoogle Scholar
- Henderson RM, Cockburn I (1994) Measuring competence: Exploring firm effects in pharmaceutical research. Strategic Management Journal, Winter Special Issue 15Google Scholar
- Herrera RA (2013) A People and its soldiers: The American citizen as soldier, 1775–1861. International Bibliography of Military History 33:9-34CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Hildebrandt GG (1999) The military production function. Defence and Peace Economics 10:247-272CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Hinge A. (2000) Australian Defence Preparedness. Australian Defence Force Academy, CanberraGoogle Scholar
- Hobbes T (2006) Leviathan. A&C Black, LondonGoogle Scholar
- Hodgson G (1988) Economics and institutions. University of Pennsylvania Press, PhiladelphiaGoogle Scholar
- Hodgson G (1993) Economics and evolution: Bringing life back into economics. University of Michigan Press, Ann ArborGoogle Scholar
- Holcombe R (2008) Why does government produce national defense? Public Choice 137:11-19CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Hummel JR (1990) National goods versus public goods: Defense, disarmament, and free riders. Review of Austrian Economics 4: 88-122Google Scholar
- Hummel JR, Lavoie D (1990) National defense and the public-goods problem. In Higgs R (Ed.) Arms, politics, and the economy: Historical and contemporary perspectives. Holmes and Meier, New York, 37-60Google Scholar
- Hutt WH (1971) Politically impossible? Institute of Economic Affairs, LondonGoogle Scholar
- Isely JA, Crowl PA (1951) The US Marines and amphibious war: Its theory, and its practice in the Pacific. Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
- Jellinek G (1900) Das Recht des modernen Staates, Band 1: Allgemeine Staatslehre. Häring, BerlinGoogle Scholar
- Jones E (2003) The European miracle. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
- Kasper W, Streit ME (1999) Institutional economics: Social order and public policy. Edward Elgar, LondonGoogle Scholar
- Kempers B, Jackson B (1992) Painting, power and patronage: The rise of the professional artist in the Italian Renaissance. Penguin Books, LondonGoogle Scholar
- Kern EM, Richter G (2014) Neue Planungs-und Steuerungsinstrumente in der Bundeswehr. SpringerGabler, PotsdamGoogle Scholar
- Kerr C, Phaal R, Probert D (2008) A strategic capabilities-based representation of the future British armed forces. International Journal of Intelligent Defence Support Systems 1:27-42Google Scholar
- Kinnaird M, Early L, Schofield, B (2003) Defence Procurement Review. Australian Government, Department of Defense, CanberraGoogle Scholar
- Kirchhoff G (Hrsg) (1986) Handbuch zur Ökonomie der Verteidigungspolitik. Walhalla-und-Praetoria-Verlag, RegensburgGoogle Scholar
- Klingen B (2011) Die politische Ökonomie der Verteidigungs- und Bündnispolitik. Nomos, Baden-BadenGoogle Scholar
- Köllner L (1982) Militär und Finanzen. Bernard & Graefe Verlag, MünchenGoogle Scholar
- Kruys GP (2001) Combat readiness with specific reference to armies. Institute for Strategic Studies, University of PretoriaGoogle Scholar
- Kusunoki K, Nonaka I, Nagata A (1998) Organizational capabilities in product development of Japanese firms: A conceptual framework and empirical findings. Organization Science 9: 699–718CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Lipow J, Plessner Y (2008) Tax efficiency and quality/quantity trade-offs in defense procurement. Defence and Peace Economics 19:21-26CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Macchiavelli N (1986) Il Principe / Der Fürst. Reclam, StuttgartGoogle Scholar
- Malešič M, Kümmel G (Eds.) (2011) Security and the military between reality and perception. Nomos, Baden-BadenGoogle Scholar
- Malizard J (2014) Dépenses militaires et croissance économique dans un contexte non linéaire. Revue économique, 65:601-618CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Malizard J (2015) Analyse économique du désarmement: une revue de littérature. Stratégique 108:71‐93Google Scholar
- Martines L (1988) Power and imagination. John Hopkins University Press, BaltimoreGoogle Scholar
- Matthews R (1986) The economics of institutions and the sources of growth. Economic Journal 96: 903–918CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- McGuire MC (2007) Economics of defense in a globalized world. In Sandler T, Hartley K (Eds.), Handbook of Defense Economics Vol.2, 623-648Google Scholar
- Milgate M (2008) Goods and commodities. In Eatwell J, Milgate M, Newman P (Eds.) The new Palgrave dictionary of economics. Macmillan, London, 546-548Google Scholar
- Milizkommission C VBS (2012) Die Bedeutung der Armee für die Schweiz: Eine ganzheitliche volkswirtschaftliche Analyse von Nutzen und Kosten. Milizkommission C VBS, BernGoogle Scholar
- Millett AR, Murray W, Watman KH (1986) The effectiveness of military organizations. International Security 11:37-71CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Mintz A (Ed.) (1992) The political economy of military spending in the United States. Routledge, London, New YorkGoogle Scholar
- Moore BA, Barnett JE (Eds.) (2014) Military psychologists’ desk reference. Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
- Moore SC, Stockfisch JA, Goldberg MS, Holroyd SM, Hildebrandt GG (1991) Measuring military readiness and sustainability. RAND Corporation, Santa MonicaGoogle Scholar
- Moran M (2006) Modern military force structures. Council on Foreign Relations, LondonGoogle Scholar
- Musgrave RA (1959) The theory of public finance. McGraw-Hill, New YorkGoogle Scholar
- NATO (2018) Communique PR/CP(2018)091: Defence expenditure of NATO countries 2011-2018. North Atlantic Treaty Organization, BruxellesGoogle Scholar
- Navarro-Galera A, Ortúzar-Maturana RI, Muñoz-Leiva F (2011) The application of life cycle costing in evaluating military investments: An empirical study at an international scale. Defence and Peace Economics 22:509-543CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Nordhaus WR, Oneal JR, Russett, B (2012) The effects of the international security environment on national military expenditures: a multicountry study. International Organization 66: 491-513CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- North DC (1990) Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
- North DC (2005) Understanding the process of economic change. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
- Oestreich G (1957) Soldatenbild, Heeresreform und Heeresgestaltung im Zeitalter des Absolutismus (Schicksalsfragen der Gegenwart, Band 1). Max Niemeyer Verlag, TübingenGoogle Scholar
- Olson M (1965) The logic of collective action. Harvard University Press, Cambridge MAGoogle Scholar
- Oman C (1991) A history of the art of war in the sixteenth century. Greenhill Books, LondonGoogle Scholar
- Ostrom E (2005) Understanding institutional diversity. Princeton University Press, PrincetonGoogle Scholar
- Pahlavi P, Ouellet É (2009) Guerre irrégulière et analyse institutionnelle: le cas de la guerre révolutionnaire de l’armée française en Algérie. Guerres mondiales et conflits contemporains 3:131-144CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Panagariya A, Shibata H (2000) Defense and welfare under rivalry. International Economic Review 41:951-969CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Paparone C (2013) The sociology of military science. Continuum, New York.Google Scholar
- Papke G (1975) Von der Miliz zum Stehenden Heer 1648-1789. In Militärgeschichtliches Forschungsamt (Hrsg) Handbuch zur Deutschen Militärgeschichte 1648-1939. Bernard & Graefe Verlag für Wehrwesen, MünchenGoogle Scholar
- Platteau JP (2000) Institutions, social norms, and economic development. Routledge, New YorkGoogle Scholar
- Poast P (2006) The economics of war. McGraw-Hill, IrwinGoogle Scholar
- Powell B, Coyne C (2003) Do pessimistic assumptions about human behavior justify government? Journal of Libertarian Studies 17:17-38Google Scholar
- Powell W, DiMaggio P (Eds.) (1991) The new institutionalism in organizational analysis. University of Chicago Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
- Powell B, Stringham E (2009) Public choice and the economic analysis of anarchy: A survey. Public Choice 140: 503-38CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Pyman M, Wilson R, Scott D (2009) The extent of single sourcing in defence procurement and its relevance as a corruption risk: A first look. Defence and Peace Economics 20:215-232CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Ravichandran T, Lertwongsatien C (2005) Effect of information systems resources and capabilities on firm performance: A resource-based perspective. Journal of Management Information Systems 21:237-276CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Reppy J (1991) On the nature and scope of Defence and Peace Economics: A comment. Defense Economics 2:269-271CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Richter G (Hrsg) (2007) Die ökonomische Modernisierung der Bundeswehr: Sachstand, Konzeptionen und Perspektiven. Springer, WiesbadenGoogle Scholar
- Ritchie N (2011) Rethinking security: a critical analysis of the Strategic Defence and Security Review. International Affairs 87:355-376CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Roberts M (1995) The military revolution, 1560–1660. In: Clifford J. Rogers (Eds) The military revolution debate. Westview Press, Boulder, 13–35CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Rodrik D (2007) One economics, many recipes: Globalization, institutions, and economic growth. Princeton University Press, Princeton NJGoogle Scholar
- Rodrik D, Subramanian A, Trebbi F (2004) Institutions rule: The primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development. Journal of Economic Growth, 9:131-165CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Rohlfs C, Sullivan R (2013) The cost-effectiveness of armored tactical wheeled vehicles for overseas US Army operations. Defence and Peace Economics 24:293-316CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Rohlfs C (2006) The government’s valuation of military life-saving in war: A cost-minimization approach. American Economic Review 96:39-44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Röpke W (1958) Jenseits von Angebot und Nachfrage. Eugen Rentsch, Erlenbach-Zürich und StuttgartGoogle Scholar
- Rothbard MN (1973) For a new liberty: Libertarian Manifesto. Macmillan, New YorkGoogle Scholar
- Rothkopf MH (2007) Thirteen reasons why the Vickrey-Clarke-Groves process is not practical. Operations Research 55: 191-197CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Rubin EL (2007) Beyond Camelot: Rethinking politics and law for the modern state. Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
- Samuelson PA (1954) The pure theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics 36:387-389CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Samuelson PA (1955) Diagrammatic exposition of a theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics 37:350-356CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Sandler T, Hartley S (Eds) (2007) Handbook of defense economics: Defense in a globalized world. Elsevier, AmsterdamGoogle Scholar
- Sandler T, Tschirhart J (1997) Club theory: Thirty years later. Public Choice 93:335-355CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Scully GW (1992) Constitutional environments and economic growth. Princeton University Press, Princeton NJGoogle Scholar
- Sechrest LJ (2007) Privately funded and built US warships in the quasi-war of 1797–1801. The Independent Review 12:101-113Google Scholar
- Sechrest LJ (2004) Public goods and private solutions in maritime history. The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 7:3–27CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Solomon B, Stone C (2013) Accrual budgeting and defence funding: Theory and simulations. Defence and Peace Economics 24:211-227CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Solow RM (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 70:65–94CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Spadafora A (2015) Georg Jellinek on values and objectivity in the legal and political sciences. Modern Intellectual History 14: 747-776CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Tellis AJ, Bially J, Layne C, McPherson M (2000) Measuring national power in the postindustrial age. RAND Corporation, Santa MonicaGoogle Scholar
- The Military Balance (2018). Institute of Strategic Studies. Routledge, LondonGoogle Scholar
- Thomas von Aquin (2001) Prooemium. In Alarcón E (Ed) Corpus Thomisticum, De ente et essentia. Ad Universitatis Studiorum Navarrensis, PamplonaGoogle Scholar
- Thompson EA (1974) Taxation and national defense. Journal of Political Economy 82:755-782Google Scholar
- Tiebout CM (1956) A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy 64:416-424CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Vaubel R (2007) Realistische Politikberatung. Schweizer Monatshefte 87:30-31Google Scholar
- Viscusi K, Aldy JE (2003). The value of a statistical life: A critical review of market estimates throughout the world. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 27: 5-76.Google Scholar
- Watson T (2017) Sociology, work and organisation. Taylor & FrancisGoogle Scholar
- Wright PM, Dunford BB, Snell SA (2001) Human resources and the resource based view of the firm. Journal of Management 27:701-721CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Yeoh PL, Roth K (1999) An empirical analysis of sustained advantage in the US pharmaceutical industry: Impact of firm resources and capabilities. Strategic Management Journal 20:637-653CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Zucker L (1987) Institutional theories of organization. American Review of Sociology 13:443-464CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copyright information
© Springer Fachmedien Wiesbaden GmbH, ein Teil von Springer Nature 2019