Consistency of Linear Forecasts in a Nonlinear Stochastic Economy
- 4 Citations
- 1.3k Downloads
Abstract
The notion of consistent expectations equilibrium is extended to economies that are described by a nonlinear stochastic system. Agents in the model do not know the nonlinear law of motion and use a simple linear forecasting rule to form their expectations. Along a stochastic consistent expectations equilibrium (SCEE), these expectations are correct in a linear statistical sense, i.e., the unconditional mean and autocovariances of the actual (but unknown) nonlinear stochastic process coincide with those of the linear stochastic process on which the agents base their beliefs. In general, the linear forecasts do not coincide with the true conditional expectation, but an SCEE is an ‘approximate rational expectations equilibrium’ in the sense that forecasting errors are unbiased and uncorrelated. Adaptive learning of SCEE is studied in an overlapping generations framework.
Keywords
Bounded rationality Expectation formation Consistent expectations Sample autocorrelation learning Path dependenceNotes
Acknowledgements
Earlier versions of this paper have been presented at the IFAC symposium Computational Economics, Finance and Engineering, Barcelona, July 6–8, 2000, the CeNDEF workshops on Economic Dynamics, Amsterdam, January 4–6, 2001 and Leiden, June 17–28, 2002, the 8th Viennese workshop on Optimal Control, Dynamic Games and Nonlinear Dynamics, Vienna, May 14–16, 2003 as well as various department seminars. Stimulating discussions with participants are gratefully acknowledged. In particular, we would like to thank Buz Brock, Jim Bullard, George Evans, Jean-Michel Grandmont and Seppo Honkapohja for stimulating discussions. This research has been supported by the Netherlands Organization for Scientific Research (NWO).
References
- Arthur, W. B., Ermoliev. Y. M., & Kaniovski, Y. (1987). Path-dependent processes and the emergence of macro-structure. European Journal of Operational Research,30, 294–303.Google Scholar
- Barnett, W. A., Gallant, A. R., Hinich, M. J., Jungeilges, J. A., Kaplan, D. T., & Jensen, M. J. (1998). A single-blind controlled competition among tests for nonlinearity and chaos. Journal of Econometrics,82, 157–192.Google Scholar
- Böhm, V., & Wenzelburger, J. (1999). Expectations, forecasting, and perfect foresight – A dynamical systems approach. Macroeconomic Dynamics,3, 167–186.Google Scholar
- Box, G. E. P., Jenkins, G. M., & Reinsel, G. C. (1994). Time series analysis. Forecasting and control (3rd ed.). Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
- Branch, W., & McGough, B. (2005). Consistent expectations and misspecification in stochastic non-linear economies. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control,29, 659–676.Google Scholar
- Branch, W. A. (2006). Restricted perceptions equilibria and learning in macroeconomics. In D. Colander (Ed.), PostWalrasian macroeconomics: Beyond the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model. New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 135–160.Google Scholar
- Bray, M. M. (1982). Learning, estimation, and the stability of rational expectations. Journal of Economic Theory,26, 318–339.Google Scholar
- Bray, M. M., & Savin, N. E. (1986). Rational expectations equilibria, learning, and model specification. Econometrica,54, 1129–1160.Google Scholar
- Brock, W. A., & Dechert, W. D. (1991). Nonlinear dynamical systems: Instability and chaos in economics. In W. Hildenbrand & H. Sonnenschein (Eds.), Handbook of mathematical economics IV. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
- Brock, W. A., & Hommes, C. H. (1997). A rational route to randomness. Econometrica,65, 1059–1095.Google Scholar
- Brock, W. A., & Hommes, C. H. (1998). Heterogeneous beliefs and routes to chaos in a simple asset pricing model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control,22, 1235–1274.Google Scholar
- Brock, W. A., Hsieh, D.A., & LeBaron, B. (1991). Nonlinear dynamics, chaos and instability: Statistical theory and economic evidence. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
- Bullard, J. (1994). Learning equilibria. Journal of Economic Theory,64, 468–485.Google Scholar
- Bullard, J., & Duffy, J. (1998). Learning and the stability of cycles. Macroeconomic Dynamics,2, 22–48.Google Scholar
- Bullard, J., & Duffy, J. (2001). Learning and excess volatility. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 5(2), 272–302.Google Scholar
- Devaney, R. L. (1989). An introduction to chaotic dynamical systems (2nd ed.). Redwood City, NJ: Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
- Evans, G. W., & Honkapohja, S. (1994). On the local stability of sunspot equilibria under adaptive learning rules. Journal of Economic Theory,64, 142–161.Google Scholar
- Evans, G. W., & Honkapohja, S. (1995). Local convergence of recursive learning to steady states and cycles in stochastic nonlinear models. Econometrica,63, 195–206.Google Scholar
- Evans, G. W., & Honkapohja, S. (2001). Learning in macroeconomics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
- Gardini, L., Hommes, C. Tramontana, F., & de Vilder, R. (2009). Forward and backward dynamics in implicitly defined overlapping generations models. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization,71, 110–129.Google Scholar
- Grandmont, J.-M. (1985). On endogenous competitive business cycles. Econometrica,53, 995–1045.Google Scholar
- Grandmont, J.-M. (1998). Expectations formation and stability in large socio-economic systems. Econometrica,66, 741–781.Google Scholar
- Guesnerie, R. (2001). Assessing rational expectations: Sunspot multiplicity and economic fluctuations. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
- Hommes, C. H. (1998). On the consistency of backward-looking expectations: The case of the cobweb. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization,33, 333–362.Google Scholar
- Hommes, C. H., & Rosser, J. B. (2001). Consistent expectations equilibria and complex dynamics in renewable resource markets. Macroeconomic Dynamics,5, 180–203.Google Scholar
- Hommes, C. H., & Sorger, G. (1998). Consistent expectations equilibria. Macroeconomic Dynamics,2, 287–321.Google Scholar
- Hommes, C. H., & Zhu, M. (2011). Behavioral learning equilibria (Technical Report, CeNDEF Working Paper). University of Amsterdam.Google Scholar
- Jungeilges, J. (2007). On chaotic consistent expectations equilibria. Analyse and Kritik,29, 269–289.Google Scholar
- Kurz, M. (1994). On rational belief equilibria. Economic Theory,4, 859–876.Google Scholar
- Lasota, A., & Mackey, M. C. (1985). Probabilistic properties of deterministic systems. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
- Lasota, A. & Mackey, M. C. (1994). Applied Mathematical Sciences: Vol. 97. Chaos, fractals and noise. Stochastic aspects of dynamics (2nd ed.). New York: Springer.Google Scholar
- Lucas, R. E. (1971). Econometric testing of the natural rate hypothesis, In O. Eckstein (Ed.), The econometrics of price determination Conference. Washington DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and Social Science Research Council.Google Scholar
- Marcet, A., & Nicolini, J. P. (2003). Recurrent hyperinflations and learning. American Economic Review,93, 1476–1498.Google Scholar
- Marcet, A., & Sargent, T. J. (1989). Convergence of least squares learning in mechanisms in self referential linear stochastic models. Journal of Economic Theory,48, 337–368.Google Scholar
- Marimon, R., Spear, S. E., & Sunder, S. (1993). Expectationally driven market volatility: An experimental study. Journal of Economic Theory,61, 74–103.Google Scholar
- Medio, A., & Raines, B. (2007). Backward dynamics in economics. the inverse limit approach. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control,31, 1633–1671.Google Scholar
- Muth, J. (1961). Rational expectations and the theory of price movements. Econometrica,29, 315–335.Google Scholar
- Nerlove, M., Grether, D. M., & Carvalho, J. L. (1979). Analysis of economic time series: A sythesis. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
- Sakai, H., & Tokumaru, H. (1980). Autocorrelations of a certain chaos. IEEE Transactions on Acoustics, Speech and Signal Processing,28, 588–590.Google Scholar
- Sargent, T. J. (1993). Bounded rationality in macroeconomics. Oxford, UK: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
- Sargent, T. J. (1999). The conquest of American inflation. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
- Schönhofer, M. (1999). Chaotic learning equilibria. Journal of Economic Theory,89, 1–20.Google Scholar
- Sögner, L., & Mitlöhner, H. (2002). Consistent expectations equilibria and learning in a stock market. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control,26, 171–185.Google Scholar
- Sorger, G. (1998). Imperfect foresight and chaos: An example of a self-fulfilling mistake. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization,33, 363–383.Google Scholar
- Stokey, N. L., & Lucas, R. E. (1989). Recursive methods in economic dynamics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
- Tuinstra, J. (2003). Beliefs equilibria in an overlapping generations model. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization,50, 145–164.Google Scholar
- Tuinstra, J., & Wagener, F. (2007). On learning equilibria. Economic Theory,30, 493–513.Google Scholar
- Woodford, M. (1990). Learning to believe in sunspots. Econometrica,58, 277–307.Google Scholar