Advertisement

Land, Housing, Growth and Inequality

  • Luigi Bonatti
Conference paper

Abstract

This paper incorporates productive assets, residential land and residential structures in a growth model with two social classes: capitalists, who invest in productive assets and housing but do not work, and workers, who invest only in housing and decide on their labor effort. It is shown that the relative price of land grows in the long run at the same rate as the economy’s GDP, while the quantity of housing services and their price grow slower than it. Moreover, numerical examples show that (i) shifting taxation away from income and towards the property of land enhances long-term GDP growth and leads in the long-run to more equalitarian (more favorable to workers) income and wealth distributions, (ii) a marginal increase in the fraction of investment expenditures in residential structures that is tax deductible reduces income and wealth inequality, (iii) a change in preferences giving more weight in the utility function to residential services leads in the long run to a distribution of income and wealth more favorable to capitalists, (iv) changes in taxation or in preferences increasing the fraction of total investment devoted to the accumulation of residential wealth rather than to the accumulation of productive assets brings about a balanced growth path characterized by a higher wealth-income ratio. Finally, endogenous fluctuations may be generated along the equilibrium trajectory converging to the balanced growth path, in a model where housing wealth and residential land are distinguished from productive capital and only fundamentals (initial endowments, preferences and technologies) drive the economy.

Keywords

Productive assets Residential structures Urban rents Land value tax 

JEL Classification

H24 O18 O41 R31 

Notes

Acknowledgements

I am very grateful to Ned Phelps for the inspiring conversations during my staying as visiting scholar at the Center on Capitalism and Society at Columbia University. I also thank the Center for its warm hospitality. For valuable research assistance, I am indebted to Riccardo Degasperi.

References

  1. Auerbach, A. J., & Hasset, K. (2015). Capital taxation in the 21st century. NBER Working Paper Series No. 20871.Google Scholar
  2. Barro, R. J., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (1995). Economic growth. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
  3. Békés, G., & Ottaviano Gianmarco, I. P. (2016). Micro-founded measurement of regional competitiveness in Europe. In C. Altomonte & G. Békés (Eds.), Measuring competitiveness in Europe: Resource allocation, granularity and trade. Brussels, Bruegel Blueprint Series (Vol. XVIV, pp. 26–50).Google Scholar
  4. Blanchflower, D. G., & Oswald, A. J. (2013). Does high home-ownership impair the labor market? NBER Working Paper No. 19079.Google Scholar
  5. Bonnet, O., Bono, P.-H., Chapelle, G., & Wasmer, É. (2014). Does housing capital contribute to inequality? A comment on Thomas Piketty’s capital in the 21st century. Sciences Po-Department of Economics, Discussion Paper 2014-07.Google Scholar
  6. Borri, N., & Reichlin, P. (2016). The housing cost disease, mimeo.Google Scholar
  7. Calvo, G., Kotlikoff, L. J., & Rodriguez, C. A. (1979). The incidence of a tax on pure rent: A new (?) reason to an old answer. Journal of Political Economy, 87, 869–874.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Cho (Stanley), S.-W., & Francis, J. L. (2011). Tax treatment of owner occupied housing and wealth inequality. Journal of Macroeconomics, 33, 42–60.Google Scholar
  9. Davis, M. A., & Heathcote, J. (2005). Housing and the business cycle. International Economic Review, 46, 751–788.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Davis, M. A., & Heathcote, J. (2007). The price and quantity of residential land in the United States. Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, 2595–2620.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Deaton, A., & Laroque, G. (2001). Housing, land prices, and growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 6, 87–105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Eaton, J. (1988). Foreign-owned land. American Economic Review, 78, 76–88.Google Scholar
  13. Feldstein, M. (1977). The surprising incidence of a tax on pure rent: A new answer to an old question. Journal of Political Economy, 85, 349–360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Frankel, M. (1962). The production function in allocation and growth: A synthesis. American Economic Review, 52, 995–1022.Google Scholar
  15. George, H. (1935). Progress and poverty: An inquiry into the cause of industrial depressions and of increase of want with increase of wealth (Fiftieth anniversary ed.). New York: Robert Schalkenbach Foundation (1st ed.: 1879).Google Scholar
  16. Gervais, M. (2002). Housing taxation and capital accumulation. Journal of Monetary Economics, 49, 1461–1489.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Glaeser, E. L., Gyourko, J., & Saks, R. E. (2005). Why have housing prices gone up? NBER Working Paper Series No. 11129.Google Scholar
  18. Grossmann, V., & Steger, T. (2016). Das house-kapital: A theory of wealth-to-income ratios. CESIFO Working Paper No. 5844.Google Scholar
  19. Hornstein, A. (2009). Problems for a fundamental theory of house prices. Economic Quarterly, 95, 1–24.Google Scholar
  20. Jordà, O., Schularick, M., & Taylor, A. M. (2014). The great mortgaging: Housing finance, crisis, and business cycles. NBER Working Paper Series No. 20501.Google Scholar
  21. Judd, K. L. (1985). Redistributive taxation in a simple perfect foresight model. Journal of Public Economics, 28, 59–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Knoll, K., Schularick, M., & Steger, T. (2014). No price like home: Global house prices, 1870–2012. CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP10166.Google Scholar
  23. Petrucci, A. (2006). The incidence of a tax on pure rent in a small open economy. Journal of Public Economics, 90, 921–933.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Phelps, E. S. (1994). Structural slumps. The modern equilibrium theory of unemployment, interest, and assets. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  25. Piazzesi, M., & Schneider, M. (2016). Housing and macroeconomics. NBER Working Paper 22354.Google Scholar
  26. Piketty, T. (2013). Capital in the twenty-first century. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  27. Piketty, T., & Zucman, G. (2014). Capital is back: Wealth-income ratios in rich countries 1700–2010. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129, 1255–1310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Ricardo, D. (1817). On the principles of political economy and taxation (1st ed. 1817). In P. Sraffa (Ed.), The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo (with the collaboration of M. H. Dobb) (11 vol., 1951–1973). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  29. Rognlie, M. (2014). A note on Piketty and diminishing returns to capital, mimeo.Google Scholar
  30. Rognlie, M. (2015). Deciphering the fall and rise in the net capital share. In Conference Draft for the Spring 2015 Brookings Panel on Economic Activity.Google Scholar
  31. Rowthorn, R. (2014). A note on Piketty’s capital in the twenty-first century. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 38, 1275–1284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Skinner, J. (1996). The dynamic efficiency cost of not taxing housing. Journal of Public Economics, 59, 397–417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Stiglitz, J. E. (2015a). New theoretical perspectives on the distribution of income and wealth among individuals: Part I. The wealth residual. NBER Working Paper Series No. 21189.Google Scholar
  34. Stiglitz, J. E. (2015b). New theoretical perspectives on the distribution of income and wealth among individuals: Part IV. Land and credit. NBER Working Paper Series No. 21192.Google Scholar
  35. Twaites, G. (2015). Why are real interest rates so low? Secular stagnation and the relative price of investment goods. Centre for Macroeconomics (CFM), Discussion Papers 1428.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of Economics and Management & School of International StudiesUniversity of TrentoMilanItaly

Personalised recommendations