The Valuation of Uncertain Income Streams and the Pricing of Options

Abstract

A simple formula is developed for the valuation of uncertain income streams consistent with rational investor behavior and equilibrium in financial markets. Applying this formula to the pricing of an option as a function of its associated stock, the Black–Scholes formula is derived even though investors can trade only at discrete points in time.

Keywords

CRRA intertemporal CAPM Pricing uncertain income streams Single-price law of markets Arbitrage State-prices Consumption-based CAPM Local expectations hypothesis Unbiased term structure Random walk Option pricing Time-additive utility Logarithmic utility Black– Scholes formula Equity risk premium puzzle Joint normality covariance theorem 

References

  1. Beja, A. 1971. “The structure of the cost of capital under uncertainty.” Review of Economic Studies 38(3), 359–368.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Black, F. and M. Scholes. 1973. “The pricing of options and corporate liabilities.” Journal of Political Economy 81, 637–654.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Blume, M. and I. Friend. 1975. “The asset structure of individual portfolios and some implications for utility functions.” Journal of Finance 10(2), 585–603.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Bogue, M. and R. Roll. 1974. “Capital budgeting of risky projects with ‘imperfect’ markets for physical capital.” Journal of Finance 29(2), 601–613.Google Scholar
  5. Cohen, R., W. Lewellen, R. Lease, and G. Schlarbaum. 1975. “Individual investor risk aversion and investment portfolio composition.” Journal of Finance 30, 605–620.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Cox, J. and S. Ross. 1975. The pricing of options for jump processes, Wharton Working Paper #2–75, University of Pennsylvania.Google Scholar
  7. Fama, E. 1970. “Multiperiod consumption-investment decisions.” American Economic Review 60(1), 163–174.Google Scholar
  8. Geske, R. 1976. The pricing of options with stochastic dividend yield, unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
  9. Gordon, M. J. and E. Shapiro. 1956. “Capital equipment analysis: the required rate of profit.” Management Science 3(1), 102–110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Granger, C. and O. Morgenstern. 1970. Predictability of stock market prices, Heath Lexington.Google Scholar
  11. Hakansson, N. 1971. “Optimal entrepreneurial decisions in a completely stochastic environment.” Management Science 17(7), 427–449.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Jensen, M. 1972. “Capital markets: theory and evidence.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 3(2).Google Scholar
  13. Kraus, A. and R. Litzenberger. 1976. “Market equilibrium in a multiperiod state preference model with logarithmic utility.” Journal of Finance (forthcoming).Google Scholar
  14. Lintner, J. 1956. “Distribution of income of corporations among dividends, retained earnings, and taxes.” American Economic Review 46(2), 97–113.Google Scholar
  15. Long, J. 1974. “Stock prices, inflation and the term structure of interest rates.” Journal of Financial Economics 1, 131–170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Merton, R. 1973a. “Theory of rational option pricing.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 4(1), 141–183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Merton, R. 1973b. “An intertemporal capital asset pricing model.” Econometrica 41, 867–880.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Merton, R. 1975. Option pricing when underlying stock returns are discontinuous, Working Paper #787–75, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.Google Scholar
  19. Miller, M. and F. Modigliani. 1961. “Dividend policy, growth and the valuation of shares.” Journal of Business 34, 411–433.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Robichek, A. and S. Myers. 1965. Optimal financing decisions, Prentice-Hall, Prentice.Google Scholar
  21. Rosenberg, B. 1972. The behavior of random variables with nonstationary variance and the distribution of security prices, Working Paper #11, Research Program in Finance, University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
  22. Rubinstein, M. 1973. “A comparative statics analysis of risk premiums,” essay 2 in four essays in the theory of competitive security markets, Ph.D. dissertation (UCLA 1971), appeared in Journal of Business.Google Scholar
  23. Rubinstein, M. 1974a. “An aggregation theorem for security markets.” Journal of Financial Economics 1(3), 225–244.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Rubinstein, M. 1974b. A discrete-time synthesis of financial theory, Working Papers #20 and #21, Research Program in Finance, University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
  25. Rubinstein, M. 1975. “Securities market efficiency in an arrow-debreu economy.” American Economic Review 65(5), 812–824.Google Scholar
  26. Rubinstein, M. 1976. “The strong case for the generalized logarithmic utility model as the premier model of financial markets.” Journal of Finance 3, 551–571.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Samuelson, P. 1973. “Proof that properly discounted present values of assets vibrate randomly.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 4(2), 369–374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Samuelson, P. and R. Merton. 1969. “A complete model of warrant pricing that maximizes utility.” Industrial Management Review 10, 17–46.Google Scholar
  29. Sharpe, W. 1964. “Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk.” Journal of Finance 19, 425–442.Google Scholar
  30. Sprenkle, C. 1961. “Warrant prices as indicators of expectations and preferences.” Yale Economic Essays 1(2), 178–231.Google Scholar
  31. Stein, C. 1973. “Estimation of the mean of a multivariate normal distribution.” Proceedings of the Prague Symposium on Asymptotic Statistics, 345–381.Google Scholar
  32. Williams, J. 1938. Theory of investment value, North Holland, Amsterdam.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2010

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.University of CaliforniaBerkleyUSA

Personalised recommendations