Advertisement

Evolution of Conventional Meaning and Conversational Principles

  • Robert Van Rooy

Abstract

In this paper we study language use and language organisation by making use of Lewisean signalling games. Standard game theoretical approaches are contrasted with evolutionary ones to analyze conventional meaning and conversational interpretation strategies. It is argued that analyzing successful communication in terms of standard game theory requires agents to be very rational and fully informed. The main goal of the paper is to show that in terms of evolutionary game theory we can motivate the emergence and self-sustaining force of (i) conventional meaning and (ii) some conversational interpretation strategies in terms of weaker and, perhaps, more plausible assumptions.

Keywords

Nash Equilibrium Replicator Dynamic Language Game Evolutionary Game Theory Cheap Talk 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Asher, N., I. Sher and M. Williams: 2001, ‘Game Theoretical Foundations for Gricean Constraints’, in R van Rooy and M. Stokhof (eds.), Proceedings of the Thirteenth Amsterdam Colloquium, ILLC, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
  2. Axelrod, R. and W. Hamilton: 1981, ‘The Evolution of Cooperation’, Science 411: 1390–1396.Google Scholar
  3. Blackwell, D.: 1953, ‘Equivalent Comparisons of Experiments’, Annals of Mathemathical Statistics 24, 265–272.Google Scholar
  4. Blutner, R.: 2000, ‘Some Aspects of Optimality in Natural Language Interpretation’, Journal of Semantics 17: 189–216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Clark, H.: 1996, Using Language, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
  6. Crawford, V. and J. Sobel: 1982, ‘Strategic Information Transmission’, Econometrica 50, 1431–1451.Google Scholar
  7. Croft, W.: 2000, Explaining Language Change: An Evolutionary Approach, Longman Linguistic Library, Harlow.Google Scholar
  8. Dretske, F.: 1981, Knowledge and the Flow of Information, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
  9. Fisher, R. A.: 1930, The Genetical Theory of Natural Selection, Oxford University Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
  10. Grafen, A.: 1990, ‘Biological Signals as Handicaps’, Journal of Theoretical Biology 144, 517–546.Google Scholar
  11. Gintis, H.: 2000, Game Theory Evolving, Princeton University Press, Princeton.Google Scholar
  12. Grice, H. P.: 1957, ‘Meaning’, Philosophical Review 66: 377–388.Google Scholar
  13. Grice, H. P.: 1967, ‘Logic and Conversation’, typescript from the William James Lectures, Harvard University. Published in P. Grice (1989), Studies in the Way of Words, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA, pp. 22–40.Google Scholar
  14. Groenendijk, J. and M. Stokhof: 1984, Studies in the Semantics of Questions and the Pragmatics of Answers, Ph.D. thesis, University of Amsterdam.Google Scholar
  15. Grosz, B., A. Joshi, and S. Weinstein: 1995, ‘Centering: A Framework for Modeling the Local Coherence of Discourse’, Computational Linguistics 21, 203–226.Google Scholar
  16. Horn, L.: 1984, ‘Towards a New Taxonomy of Pragmatic Inference: Q-based and Rbased Implicature’, in D. Schiffrin (ed.), Meaning, Form, and Use in Context: Linguistic Applications, GURT84, Washington; Georgetown University Press, pp. 11–42.Google Scholar
  17. Hurd, P.: 1995, ‘Communication in Discrete Action-Response Games’, Journal of Theoretical Biology 174, 217–222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Hurford, J.: 1989, ‘Biological Evolution of the Saussurian Sign as a Component of the Language Acquisition Device’, Lingua 77, 187–222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Hurford, J.: 2000, ‘The Emergence of Syntax’, in C. Knight, M. Studdert-Kennedy and J. Hurford (eds.), The Evolutionary Emergence of Language: Social Function and the Origins of Linguistic Form, (editorial introduction to section on syntax), Cambridge University Press, pp. 219–230.Google Scholar
  20. Kandori, M., G. J. Mailath, and R. Rob: 1993, ‘Learning, Mutation, and Long Run Equilibria in Games’, Econometrica 61, 29–56.Google Scholar
  21. Karttunen, L.: 1977, ‘Syntax and Semantics of Questions’, Linguistics and Philosophy 1, 3–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Kirby, S. and J. Hurford: 2001, ‘The Emergence of Linguistic Structure: An Overview of the Iterated Learning Model’, in D. Parisi and A. Cangelosi (eds.), Simulating the Evolution of Language, Springer Verlag, Berlin.Google Scholar
  23. Komarova, N., P. Niyogi, and M. Nowak: 2001, ‘The Evolutionary Dynamics of Grammar Acquisition’, Journal of Theoretical Biology 209, 43–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Lachmann, M., Sz. Szamado, and C. Bergstrom: manuscript, ‘The Peacock, the Sparrow, and Evolution of Human Language’, Santa Fe Institute working paper nr. 00-12-74.Google Scholar
  25. Levinson, S.: 2000, Presumptive Meanings. The Theory of Generalized Conversational Implicatures, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
  26. Lewis, D.: 1969, Convention, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
  27. Lightfoot, D. W.: 1991, How to Set Parameters: Arguments from Language Change, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
  28. Maynard-Smith, J. and G. R. Price: 1973, ‘The Logic of Animal Conflict’, Nature 146, 15–18.Google Scholar
  29. Maynard-Smith, J.: 1982, Evolution and the Theory of Games, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
  30. Maynard-Smith, J. and D. Harper: 1995, ‘Animal Signals: Models and Terminology’, Journal of Theoretical Biology 177, 305–311.Google Scholar
  31. McCarthy, J.: 1980, ‘Circumscription — A Form of Non-Monotonic Reasoning’, Artificial Intelligence 13, 27–39.Google Scholar
  32. Millikan, R. G.: 1984, Language, Thought, and Other Biological Categories, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
  33. Nowak, M. and D. Krakauer: 1999, ‘The Evolution of Language’, Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 96, 8028–8033.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Oliphant, M.: 1996, ‘The Dilemma of Saussurean Communication’, BioSystems 37, 31–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Osborne, M. and A. Rubinstein: 1994, A course in Game Theory, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
  36. Parikh, P.: 1991, ‘Communication and Strategic Inference’, Linguistics and Philosophy, 14, 473–513.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Parikh, P.: 2001, The Use of Language, CSLI Publications, Stanford, CA.Google Scholar
  38. Rooy, R. van: 2003, ‘Quality and Quantity of Information Exchange’, Journal of Logic, Language and Information 12, 423–451.Google Scholar
  39. Rooy, R. van: in press, ‘Signaling Games Select Horn Strategies’, Linguistics and Philosophy, to appear.Google Scholar
  40. Rooy, R. van and K. Schulz: manuscript, ‘Pragmatic Meaning and Non-Monotonic Reasoning: The Case of Exhaustive Interpretation’, University of Amsterdam.Google Scholar
  41. Schelling, T.: 1960, The Strategy of Conflict, Oxford University Press, New York.Google Scholar
  42. Schiffer, S.: 1972, Meaning, Clarendon Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
  43. Selten, R.: 1980, ‘A Note on Evolutionary Stable Strategies in Asymmetric Animal Contests’, Journal of Theoretical Biology 84, 93–101.Google Scholar
  44. Searle, J. R.: 1969, Speech Acts, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
  45. Shannon, C.: 1948, ‘The Mathematical Theory of Communication’, Bell System Technical Journal 27, 379–423, 623–656.Google Scholar
  46. Skyrms, B.: 1994, ‘Darwin Meets The Logic of Decision: Correlation in Evolutionary Game Theory’, Philosophy of Science 61, 503–528.Google Scholar
  47. Skyrms, B.: 1996, Evolution of the Social Contract, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
  48. Skyrms, B.: manuscript, ‘Signals, Evolution and the Explanatory Power of Transient Information’, University of California, Irvine.Google Scholar
  49. Spence, M.: 1973, ‘Job Market Signalling’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 87, 355–374.Google Scholar
  50. Sperber, D. and D. Wilson: 1986, Relevance, Harvard University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
  51. Steels, L.: 2000, ‘The Emergence of Grammar in Communicating Autonomous Robotic Agents’, in W. Horn (ed.), Proceedings of European Conference on Artificial Intelligence, ECAI2000, nr. CONF14, Amsterdam: IOS Press, pp. 764–769.Google Scholar
  52. Strawson, P. F.: 1964, ‘Intention and Convention in Speech Acts’, Philosophical Review 75, 439–460.Google Scholar
  53. Taylor, P. and L. Jonker: 1978, ‘Evolutionary Stable Strategies and Game Dynamics’, Mathematical Biosciences 40, 145–156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Tuyls, K. et al.: this volume, ‘An Evolutionary Game Theoretical Perspective on Learning in Multi-Agent Systems’, Knowledge, Rationality and Action.Google Scholar
  55. Vanderschraaf, P.: 1995, ‘Convention as Correlated Equilibrium’, Erkenntnis 42, 65–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Wärneryd, K.: 1993, ‘Cheap Talk, Coordination, and Evolutionary Stability’, Games and Economic Behavior 5, 532–546.Google Scholar
  57. Weibull, J. W.: 1995) Evolutionary Game Theory, MIT Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
  58. Wray, A.: 1998, ‘Protolanguage as a Holistic System for Social Interaction’, Language and Communication 19, 47–67.Google Scholar
  59. Young, H. P.: 1993, ‘The Evolution of Conventions’, Econometrica 61, 57–84.Google Scholar
  60. Zahavi, A.: 1975, ‘Mate Selection — A Delection for a Handicap’, Journal of Theoretical Biology 53, 205–214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Kluwer Academic Publishers 2004

Authors and Affiliations

  • Robert Van Rooy
    • 1
  1. 1.ILLC Department of HumanitiesUniversity of AmsterdamAmsterdamThe Netherlands

Personalised recommendations