Skip to main content

Origins and Implications of Family Structure Across Italian Provinces in Historical Perspective

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Cliometrics of the Family

Part of the book series: Studies in Economic History ((SEH))

Abstract

In this chapter we review the literature on the origins and implications of family structure in historical perspective with a focus on Italian provinces. Furthermore, we present newly collected data on three of the main features of family structure: the female mean age at marriage, the female celibacy rate, and the fraction of illegitimate births. Data are collected at the provincial level for 1871. The analysis of the data allows us to confirm and quantify the geographic differentiation in family patterns across the country. We also illustrate the links between family structure and a set of socioeconomic outcomes, in the short, medium, and long run.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 149.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 199.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In the demographic literature, delayed marriage and high celibacy are also referred to as “Malthusian preventive checks” on fertility, that is, behaviors aimed at controlling reproduction, consciously or not, which differ from the “positive checks,” namely, mortality by famine, wars, or diseases (Malthus 1798). An implication of the “preventive checks” is the possibility of high illegitimacy rates.

  2. 2.

    Todd obtains his classification by applying the “regressive method” due to Bloch (1949). Starting with contemporaneous census data for Western Europe, mostly collected for the 1950s and 1960s, he goes back to historical data. By comparison he can establish strong persistence of the observed family types back to the Middle Age. Outside Europe, Todd also classifies three additional family types, i.e., the endogamous community, anomic, and African families.

  3. 3.

    We refer to the literature cited by Dennison and Ogilvie (2014) for further details.

  4. 4.

    The latter are Belluno, Padua, Rovigo, Treviso, Udine, Venice, Verona, and Vicenza.

  5. 5.

    The maps do not include the area in the North corresponding to Trentino, which was not part of the Kingdom of Italy in 1871 but entered afterward. See the Appendix for definitions and sources of variables.

  6. 6.

    Todd (1984) also proposes an alternative classification criterion based on the relationship between husband and wife as captured by the degree of feminism, which is at its highest under matrilineality, at its lowest under patrilineality, and at an intermediate level under bilaterality. A family system is considered matrilinear if it assigns a prominent social role to the kinship of the wife.

  7. 7.

    Italy exhibits rich variation in family types also in an international comparison. For instance, Spain exhibits only two family types: the stem in the North and the egalitarian nuclear in the South, while England presents the egalitarian nuclear family in the East and the incomplete stem in the West.

  8. 8.

    The threshold for late age at marriage is not uniquely defined in the literature. For example, Carmichael et al. (2011) set it at 24 for women and 27 for men, whereas Dennison and Ogilvie (2014) at 23–24 years of age for women.

  9. 9.

    Data on male mean age at marriage (again adjusted to exclude marriages where the bride is older than 45) reveal that the relevant range for men is between 27 and 32, with a limited age difference between grooms and brides ranging from 2 to 5.

  10. 10.

    To account for female age at marriage, Bertocchi and Bozzano (2015) propose an alternative measure based on data from Barbagli (1987) on the percentage of women married below the age of 15 in 1872–1875. The original source is DIRSTAT (1877). However, information is available only at the regional level. Consistent with the variables presented here, on average women marry before age 15 years in only 3% of the regions, even though the figure is as high as 13% in the case of Sicily.

  11. 11.

    As an alternative measure, Livi Bacci (1980) employs the celibacy rate for women between age 50 and 54.

  12. 12.

    More recently Voigtlander and Voth (2013) specify that high celibacy rates range between 10 and 30% depending on time and place.

  13. 13.

    Rome entered the unified Kingdom of Italy in 1871 but the datum is missing for this year in MAIC (1874).

  14. 14.

    Campa et al. (2011) employ a measure of the gender gap in literacy in 1911 as an instrument for gender culture, which is in turn shown to affect the present gender gap in employment.

  15. 15.

    In the literature on gender inequality, early age at marriage for girls is widely recognized as a good measure of female agency and subordination of women in society. Additional information is provided by the spousal age gap and by male age at marriage. According to our data, male age at marriage is highly correlated with female age at marriage (70%), while spousal age gap is poorly correlated (30%).

  16. 16.

    Turning to family types, height is correlated negatively with the presence of the egalitarian nuclear family type with early marriage and positively with that of the incomplete stem family type. Literacy is negatively correlated with the egalitarian nuclear family with early marriage and positively with the egalitarian nuclear family with late marriage. Female to male literacy is negatively linked to the egalitarian nuclear family with early marriage. The crude birth rate in 1871 is correlated positively with the incomplete stem family type and negatively with the communitarian family, while the same variable in 1881 is positively correlated with the egalitarian nuclear family with early marriage and negatively with the communitarian family. These correlations are not reported in Table 6.2 for simplicity.

  17. 17.

    We refer to the Appendix for sources and further details on the variables included in this analysis.

References

  • A’Hearn B, Vecchi G (2011) Statura. In: Vecchi G (ed) In ricchezza e in povertà: il benessere degli italiani dall’unità a oggi. Il Mulino, Bologna, pp 37–72

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina AF, Giuliano P (2010) The power of the family. J Econ Growth 15:93–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina AF, Giuliano P (2014) Family ties. In: Aghion P, Durlauf S (eds) Handbook of economic growth, vol 2. North Holland, Oxford, pp 177–215

    Google Scholar 

  • Banfield E (1958) The moral basis of a backward society. Free, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Barbagli M (1987) Sistemi di Formazione della Famiglia in Italia. Bollettino di Demografia Storica 2:80–127

    Google Scholar 

  • Barbagli M (1991) Three household formation systems in eighteenth- and nineteenth-century Italy. In: Kertzer D, Saller R (eds) The family in Italy from the antiquity to the present. New Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Bertocchi G, Bozzano M (2015) Family structure and the education gender gap: evidence from Italian provinces. CESifo Econ Stud 61:263–300

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertocchi G, Bozzano M (2016) Women, medieval commerce, and the education gender gap. J Comp Econ 44:496–521

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bisin A, Verdier T (2000) Beyond the melting pot: cultural transmission, marriage, and the evolution of ethnic and religious traits. Q J Econ 115:955–988

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloch M (1949) Apologie pour l’Histoire ou Métier d’Historien. Librairie Armand Colin, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Bozzano M (2017) On the historical roots of women’s empowerment across Italian provinces: religion or family culture? Eur J Polit Econ 49:24–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campa P, Casarico A, Profeta P (2011) Gender culture and gender gap in employment. CESifo Econ Stud 57(1):156–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carmichael S, De Moor T, van Zanden JL (2011) Introduction. Hist Fam 16:309–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carmichael SG, De Pleijt A, van Zanden JL, De Moor T (2016) The European marriage pattern and its measurement. J Econ Hist 76:196–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ciccarelli C, Fenoaltea S (2013) Through the magnifying glass: provincial aspects of industrial growth in post-unification Italy. Econ Hist Rev 66:57–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Curtis DR (2014) The EMP in pre-industrial Italy: some notes. Mimeo, Leiden University

    Google Scholar 

  • Del Panta L, Livi Bacci M, Pinto G, Sonnino E (1996) La Popolazione Italiana dal Medioevo a Oggi. Laterza, Rome

    Google Scholar 

  • De Moor T, van Zanden JL (2010) Girl power: the European marriage pattern and labour markets in the North Sea region in the late medieval and early modern period. Econ Hist Rev 63:1–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dennison T, Ogilvie S (2014) Does the European marriage pattern explain economic growth? J Econ Hist 74:651–693

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dennison T, Ogilvie S (2016) Institutions, demography, and economic growth. J Econ Hist 76:215–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dilli S (2016) Family systems and the historical roots of global gaps in democracy. Econ Hist Develop Regions 31:82–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dilli S, Rijpma A, Carmichael S (2015) Achieving gender equality: development versus historical legacies. CESifo Econ Stud 61:301–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DIRSTAT (1877) Popolazione. Movimento dello Stato Civile. Anno 1875. Tipografia Cenniniana, Rome

    Google Scholar 

  • Duranton G, Rodriguez-Pose A, Sandall R (2009) Family types and the persistence of regional disparities in Europe. Econ Geogr 85:23–47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernández R, Fogli A (2009) Culture: an empirical investigation of beliefs, work, and fertility. Am Econ J Macroecon 1(1):146–177

    Google Scholar 

  • Foreman-Peck J (2011) The Western European marriage pattern and economic development. Explor Econ Hist 48:292–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galasso V, Profeta P (2018) When the state mirrors the family: the design of pension systems. J Eur Econ Assoc 16:1712–1763

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greif A (2006) Family structure, institutions, and growth: the origins and implications of Western corporations. Am Econ Rev 96:308–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greif A, Tabellini G (2017) The clan and the corporation: sustaining cooperation in China and Europe. J Comp Econ 45:1–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guiso L, Sapienza P, Zingales L (2006) Does culture affect economic outcomes? J Econ Perspect 20:23–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hajnal J (1965) European marriage patterns in perspective. In: Glass DV, Eversley DEC (eds) Population in history: essays in historical demography. Edward Arnold, London, pp 101–143

    Google Scholar 

  • Hajnal J (1982) Two kinds of preindustrial household formation system. Popul Dev Rev 8:449–494

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herlihy D, Klapisch-Zuber C (1978). Les Toscans et Leurs Familles. Une Etude du Catasto Florentin de 1427. Editions de l’Ecole des Hautes Etudes en Sciences Sociales, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • ISTAT (2009) Atlante Statistico dei Comuni. Settore Ambiente e Territorio, Istituto Nazionale di Statistica, Rome

    Google Scholar 

  • Istituto Guglielmo Tagliacarne (2011) Reddito e Occupazione nelle Province Italiane dal 1861 ad Oggi. Istituto Guglielmo Tagliacarne, Rome

    Google Scholar 

  • Kertzer D, Brettell C (1987) Advances in Italian and Iberian family history. J Fam Hist 12:87–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kertzer D, Hogan D (1991) Reflections on the European marriage pattern: sharecropping and proletarianisation in Casalecchio, Italy, 1861-1921. J Fam Hist 16:31–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laslett P (1977) Family life and illicit love in earlier generations. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Laslett P (1983) Family and household as work group and kin group: areas of traditional Europe compared. In: Wall R, Robin J, Laslett P (eds) Family forms in historic Europe. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Laslett P, Wall R (1972) Household and family in past time. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Livi Bacci M (1980) Donna, Fecondità e Figli. Il Mulino, Bologna

    Google Scholar 

  • MAIC (1872) Censimento della Popolazione del Regno d’Italia al 31 Dicembre 1871. Stamperia Reale, Rome

    Google Scholar 

  • MAIC (1874) Statistica del Regno d’Italia. Popolazione. Movimento dello Stato Civile nell’Anno 1871. Stamperia Reale, Florence

    Google Scholar 

  • MAIC (1875) Statistica del Regno d’Italia. Popolazione. Movimento dello Stato Civile nell’Anno 1872. Stamperia Reale, Rome

    Google Scholar 

  • MAIC (1882) Statistica del Regno d’Italia. Popolazione. Movimento dello Stato Civile. Anno XX – 1881. Tipografia Bodoniana, Rome

    Google Scholar 

  • MAIC (1883) Censimento della Popolazione del Regno d’Italia al 31 Dicembre 1881. Tipografia Bodoniana, Rome

    Google Scholar 

  • Malthus TR (1798) An essay on the principle of population. J Johnson, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Silverman S (1968) Agricultural organization, social structure, and values in Italy: amoral familism reconsidered. Am Anthropol 70:1–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silverman SF (1975) Three bells of civilization: the life of an Italian Hill Town. Columbia University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Todd E (1984) L’Enfance du Monde, Structures Familiales et Developpement. Seuil, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Todd E (1985) The explanation of ideology: family structures and social system. Basil Blackwell, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Todd E (1990) L’Invention de l’Europe. Seuil, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Tur-Prats A (2018) Family types and intimate-partner violence: a historical perspective. Rev Econ Stat. (forthcoming)

    Google Scholar 

  • Viazzo PP (2003) What’s so special about the Mediterranean? Thirty years of research on household and family in Italy. Continuity Change 18:111–137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Voigtlander N, Voth H-J (2013) How the West ‘invented’ fertility restriction. Am Econ Rev 103:2227–2264

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank three reviewers for their comments and suggestions. Generous financial support from Fondazione Cassa Risparmio di Modena and the Italian University Ministry is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding authors

Correspondence to Graziella Bertocchi or Monica Bozzano .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

Table 6.4 Summary statistics

6.1.1 Description of Variables

6.1.1.1 (A) Family Structure Data

Female mean age at marriage

We collect data from MAIC (1872, vol. 2) on the age of all brides who got married in 1871. Data are available by age group as follows: below 20, 20–24, 25–29, 30–44, 45–59, and over 60.

Share of brides aged 20 or less

We compute the percentage of brides aged 20 or less over the total number of marriages in 1871. Data are from MAIC (1872, vol. 2).

Female celibacy rate (over age 50)

Census 1871 provides detailed information on the marital status of the population disaggregated by gender and by year of age. For each province, we collect data on the age-specific marital status and calculate our indicator as the number of female celibates aged 50 or more over the total number of women in the same age range. The source is MAIC (1872, vol. 2).

Illegitimacy rate

This indicator is calculated from life statistics in 1871 (MAIC 1874). Births are disaggregated into legitimate, illegitimate, and “esposti” (i.e., abandoned infants). In this work the illegitimacy rate is calculated taking into account both out-of-wedlock births and abandoned infants over the total number of births in the same year. For Rome (and Comarca) data refers to 1872 (MAIC 1875).

Nuclearity

We define a dummy variable taking value 1 if the province was dominated by nuclear residential habits, 0 if by complex ones. Information is from Todd (1990).

Family types

These variables are taken from Bertocchi and Bozzano (2015), who adapt the classification proposed by Todd (1990) to the Italian specific regional differentiation following Hajnal (1982), Barbagli (1987), and Del Panta et al. (1996). Provinces are coded according to a set of four dummies, one for each family type, i.e., egalitarian nuclear with late marriage, incomplete stem, communitarian, and egalitarian nuclear family with early marriage.

6.1.1.2 (B) 1871 and 1881 Data

Height

Since historical data about income or wealth for Italian provinces are not available, we employ heights as a proxy. Data on heights refer to the mean height of military conscripts aged 20 at the provincial level and are taken from A’Hearn and Vecchi (2011, Table S3). We employ data referring to 1871 and 1881.

Industrialization

Data on industrialization at the provincial level are taken from Ciccarelli and Fenoaltea (2013, Table 2). The variable is a provincial index of relative industrialization calculated on the basis of census data as the share of industrial value added, excluding construction, over the share of the male population over age 15. We employ data referring to 1871 and 1881.

Human capital

We collect data on literacy, female literacy, and male literacy for population aged 20 or more, both for 1871 and 1881, from the censuses (MAIC 1872, 1883). We also obtain a measure of equality in human capital accumulation as the female to male ratio of literacy rates in both years: this measure ranges between 0 (perfect inequality) and 1 (perfect equality) and is therefore increasing in gender equality.

Crude birth rate

Our fertility measure is the standard one. We collect data on total births in 1871 and 1881 for each province, and we calculate the crude birth rate as the number of live births (legitimates, illegitimate, and “esposti”) per 1000 inhabitants. The source is MAIC (1874, 1882; for Rome, MAIC 1875).

6.1.1.3 (C) 2001 Data

Income

We use the natural logarithm of total value added per capita in 2001 (Italian lira, constant prices, base year 2000). The source is Istituto Guglielmo Tagliacarne (2011).

Labor market variables

We employ two variables taken from Bozzano (2017). The first refers to the female to male ratio of the labor force participation rate, defined as female labor force participation rate over male labor force participation rate. The second is the female to male ratio in economic leadership, defined as the share of women who are in charge of enterprises or in top managerial positions over the share of men employed in the same positions. Both variables are elaborated from the 2001 census and take values between 0 (perfect inequality between women and men) and 1 (perfect equality), so that they increase in gender equality.

Education variables

We employ variables taken from Bertocchi and Bozzano (2015), who collected data on female and male secondary and tertiary attainment for 2001 from the national census (ISTAT 2009) and computed female to male ratios. Both variables are weighted by female and male population aged 19 or more. The first variable is defined as the ratio between females with at least a high school diploma over female population over age 19 and males with at least a high school diploma over male population over age 19. Likewise, the second variable is the ratio between females with a university degree over female population over age 19 and males with a university degree over male population over age 19.

Fertility rate

This variable is defined as the average number of children per women aged 15–49 (i.e., total fertility rate net of immigration fertility rate) and measured in 2001 (ISTAT 2009).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Bertocchi, G., Bozzano, M. (2019). Origins and Implications of Family Structure Across Italian Provinces in Historical Perspective. In: Diebolt, C., Rijpma, A., Carmichael, S., Dilli, S., Störmer, C. (eds) Cliometrics of the Family. Studies in Economic History. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-99480-2_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics