Skip to main content

Part of the book series: Palgrave Studies in Economic History ((PEHS))

  • 315 Accesses

Abstract

The purpose of this introductory chapter is twofold. First, the author presents a survey of the debate about growth in ‘natural resource–intensive economies’ and places herself in the literature. Rejecting the idea that natural resource industries are doomed to slow growth, the chapter shows that industries based on natural resource may have been highly innovative, knowledge-based, dynamic, and high-performing, historically as well as today. Second, the author discusses the literature about institutions, organisations and economic growth and sets the basis for the historical empirical approach of knowledge organisations aimed to develop knowledge for mining in Norway. Finally, the used concepts, the definitions, the sources, and the main questions are outlined.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 89.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    S. Ville and O. Wicken , “The Dynamics of Resource-Based Economic Development: Evidence from Australia and Norway”, Industrial and Corporate Change, Volume 22, Issue 5, (1 October 2013), p. 14.

  2. 2.

    D. North , “Location Theory and Regional Economic Growth”, Journal of Political Economy 63 (1955), p. 254.

  3. 3.

    K. Smith , “Innovation and growth in resource-based economies”, in CEDA, Competing from Australia (Australia, 2007), p. 53.

  4. 4.

    M. Vernengo, “Technology, Finance, and Dependency: Latin American Radical Political Economy in Retrospect”, Review of Radical Political Economics, Vol. 38, No. 4 (2006), pp. 552–553.

  5. 5.

    R. Prebisch , The Economic Development of Latin America and Its Principal Problems (New York, 1950).

  6. 6.

    J. D. Sachs and A. M. Warner , “The curse of natural resources”, European Economic Review 45, 4–6 (2001), pp. 827–838.

  7. 7.

    “The Dutch Disease” The Economist, (1977), pp. 82–83.

  8. 8.

    P. Collier and A. Hoeffler, “Greed and grievance in civil wars”, Oxford Economic Papers, 56 (2004), pp. 663–695.

  9. 9.

    See, for example, T. L. Karl, The Paradox of Plenty (Berkeley, 1997); S. Andrade and J. Morales, “The Role of the Natural Resource Curse in Preventing Development in Politically Unstable Countries: Case Studies of Angola and Bolivia”, Institute for Advanced Development Studies, Development Research Working Paper Series No. 11 (2007); F. van der Ploeg, “Natural Resources: Curse or Blessing?”, Journal of Economic Literature, (2011).

  10. 10.

    F. van der Ploeg, “Natural Resources: Curse or Blessing?”, Journal of Economic Literature, (2011), p. 2.

  11. 11.

    T. L. Karl, The Paradox of Plenty (Berkeley, 1997).

  12. 12.

    T. Gylfason and G. Zoega , “Inequality and Economic Growth: Do Natural Resources Matter?”, in Inequality and Growth: Theory and Policy Implications, Theo Eicher and Stephen Turnovsky (eds), (MIT Press, 2003).

  13. 13.

    T. Gylfason, “Natural Resources, Education and Economic Development”, European Economic Review 45 (2001), pp. 847–859.

  14. 14.

    E. Suslova and N. Volchkova, “Human Capital, Industrial Growth and Resource Curse”, State University Higher School of Economics: WP 13/2007/11 CAS Working Paper Series, p. 4.

  15. 15.

    For a review of literature on this subject, see B. Nelson and A. Behar, “Natural Resources, Growth and Spatially-Based Development: A View of the Literature”, world development report, Reshaping Economic Geography, 7 February 2008.

  16. 16.

    J. Viner, “International Trade and Economic Development”, Louvain Economic Review, volume 20, issue 1 (February 1954), p. 72; D. North, “Location Theory and Regional Economic Growth”, Journal of Political Economy 63 (1955), p. 252.

  17. 17.

    D. De Ferranti et al. From Natural Resources to the Knowledge Economy (Washington, DC, 2002), p. 6.

  18. 18.

    W. Martin, and D. Mitra, “Productivity Growth and convergence in Agriculture and Manufacturing”, Economic Development and Cultural Change, vol. 49, issue 2 (2001), 403–22; G. Wright , G. and J. W. Czelusta, “Resource-Based Growth Past and Present”, in D. Lederman and W. F. Maloney (eds.), Natural Resources: Neither Curse nor Destiny, chapter 7 (Washington, DC, 2007).

  19. 19.

    K. Smith , “Innovation and growth in resource-based economies”, in CEDA, Competing from Australia (Australia, 2007), p. 53.

  20. 20.

    F. Hodne and O. H. Grytten, Norsk økonomi i det nittende århundre (Bergen, 2000), p. 97.

  21. 21.

    O. Wicken , “The Norwegian Path Creating and Building Enabling Sectors”, working paper, Centre for Technology, Innovation and Culture, University of Oslo, 2010, p. 17; Norges Officielle Statistikk, Nasjonalregnskap 1900–1929 (Oslo, 1953); Norges Offisielle Statistikk, Nasjonalregnskap 1930–1939 og 1946–1951 (Oslo, 1952).

  22. 22.

    World Data Bank, World Development Indicators (WDI) & Global Development Finance (GDF).

  23. 23.

    J. Fagerberg et al. “Innovation-systems, path-dependency and policy: The co-evolution of science, technology and innovation policy and industrial structure in a small, resource-based economy”, DIME Working paper in the series on “Dynamics of Knowledge Accumulation, Competitiveness, Regional Cohesion and Economic Policies”, 2008.

  24. 24.

    H. Hveem, “Developing an Open Economy: Norway’s Transformation, 1845–1975”, in Diverging Paths Comparing a Century of Scandinavian and Latin American Economic Development, M. Blomström and P. Meller (eds.), (Washington, DC, 1991), p. 130; F. Hodne and O. H. Grytten, Norsk økonomi i det nittende århundre (Bergen, 2000), pp. 16–17.

  25. 25.

    T. Bergh et al. Norge fra u-land til i-land: vekst og utviklingslinjer 1830–1980, (Oslo, 1983), p. 36.

  26. 26.

    Norway has had small differences in income distribution according to UNDP Income Gini coefficient: Gini Coefficient. Retrieved from UNDP: http://hdr.undp.org/en/content/income-gini-coefficient [accessed 2 March 2017]. It measures the deviation of the distribution of income among individuals or households within a country from a perfectly equal distribution. A value of 0 represents absolute equality; a value of 100, absolute inequality.

  27. 27.

    United Nations Development Programme, Human Development Reports: http://hdr.undp.org/en/data [accessed 13.04 2018].

  28. 28.

    M. Blomström and P. Meller (eds.), Diverging Paths Comparing a Century of Scandinavian and Latin American Economic Development (Washington, DC, 1991), p. vii.

  29. 29.

    K. Smith , “Innovation and growth in resource-based economies”, in CEDA, Competing from Australia (Australia, 2007), p. 7.

  30. 30.

    C. Nuur and S. Laestadius, “Anomalies in the resource curse paradigm: the case of Sweden”. Trieta research report, The Royal Institute of Technology, KTH, 2009, pp. 46–47.

  31. 31.

    P. David , G. and Wright , “Increasing Returns and the Genesis of American Resource Abundance”, Oxford Journals, vol. 6, issue 2 (1997), pp. 210–218.

  32. 32.

    UNCTAD, World Investment Report 2001 Promoting Linkages (New York and Geneva, 2001).

  33. 33.

    D. De Ferranti et al. From Natural Resources to the Knowledge Economy (Washington, DC, 2002), p. 52.

  34. 34.

    See, for example, A. D. Andersen, “Towards a new approach to natural resources and development: the role of learning, innovation and linkage dynamics”. Int. J. Technological Learning, Innovation and Development, vol. 5 2012. (3); D. De Ferranti et al. From Natural Resources to the Knowledge Economy (Washington, DC, 2002); H. Hirsch-Kreinsen et al., “Low-Tech Industries and the Knowledge Economy: State of the Art and Research Challenges”, PILOT Policy and Innovation in Low-Tech, STEP – Centre for Innovation Research (Oslo, 2003); S. Ville and O. Wicken , “The Dynamics of Resource-Based Economic Development: Evidence from Australia and Norway”, Industrial and Corporate Change, Volume 22, Issue 5, (1 October 2013).

  35. 35.

    O. Wicken , “The Norwegian Path Creating and Building Enabling Sectors”, working paper, Centre for Technology, Innovation and Culture, University of Oslo, 2010, pp. 4–5.

  36. 36.

    H. Hirsch-Kreinsen et al., “Low-Tech Industries and the Knowledge Economy: State of the Art and Research Challenges”, PILOT Policy and Innovation in Low-Tech, STEP – Centre for Innovation Research (Oslo, 2003), p. 22.

  37. 37.

    Wicken, “The Norwegian Path Creating and Building Enabling Sectors”, working paper, Centre for Technology, Innovation and Culture, University of Oslo, 2010, p. 2.

  38. 38.

    S. Ville and O. Wicken , “The Dynamics of Resource-Based Economic Development: Evidence from Australia and Norway”, Industrial and Corporate Change, Volume 22, Issue 5, (1 October 2013), p. 37.

  39. 39.

    B. Sæther, A. Isaksen and A. Karlsen, “Innovation by co-evolution in natural resource industries: The Norwegian experience”, Geoforum, vol. 42, Issue 3, June (2011); Å. Cappelen and L. Mjøset, “Can Norway be a Role Model for Natural Resource Abundant Countries?”, in Development Success: Historical Accounts from More Advanced Countries, A. K. Fosu (ed.) (Oxford, 2013); E. R. Larsen, “Are Rich Countries Immune to the resource Curse? Evidence from Norway’s Management of Its Oil Riches”, Discussion paper 362 Statistics Norway (Oslo, 2003); J. A. Frankel, “The Natural Resource Curse: A survey”, NBER Working paper 15836 (Cambridge, 2010).

  40. 40.

    Wrigley, E. A. Energy and the Industrial Revolution. Cambridge (Massachusetts, 2010).

  41. 41.

    P. David , G. and Wright , “Increasing Returns and the Genesis of American Resource Abundance”, Oxford Journals, vol. 6, issue 2 (1997), pp. 204–205.

  42. 42.

    S. Kuznets , Economic Growth and structure (New York, 1965), p. 84.

  43. 43.

    D. C. North , “Economic Performance Through Time: The Limits to Knowledge”, EconWPA, Economic History, 9612004 (1996), p. 9.

  44. 44.

    K. Bruland and K. Smith , “Knowledge Flows and Catching-Up Industrialization in the Nordic Countries The Roles of Patent Systems”, in H. Odagiri et al. Intellectual property rights, development and catch-up an International comparative study (Oxford, 2010), pp. 63–94.

  45. 45.

    J. Mokyr , The Enlightened Economy (New Haven, 2009), pp. 4, 17, and 291.

  46. 46.

    D. Kline and N. Rosenberg , “An Overview of Innovation”, in R. Landau and N. Rosenberg (eds.) The Positive Sum Strategy: Harnessing Technology for Economic Growth (Washington, DC, 1986), p. 279.

  47. 47.

    B.-Å. Lundvall , National Systems of Innovation (London, 1992), p. 1.

  48. 48.

    D. C. North , “New institutional economics and development” (Washington, DC, 1993), pp. 6 and 97.

  49. 49.

    C. Edquist , “The Systems of Innovation Approach and Innovation Policy: An account of the state of the art” (Aalborg, 2001), p. 6.

  50. 50.

    S. Kuznets , Economic Growth and structure (New York, 1965), pp. 111–112.

  51. 51.

    D. C. North , “Institutions” in The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 5, No. 1, (1991), p. 97.

  52. 52.

    K. Bruland , “Skills, learning and the International Diffusion of Technology: a Perspective on Scandinavian Industrialization”, in M. Berg and K. Bruland (eds.), Technological Revolutions in Europe (Cheltenham, 1998), p. 161.

  53. 53.

    D. C. North , “Institutions” in The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 5, No. 1, (1991), p. 97.

  54. 54.

    A. Greif , Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade (Cambridge, 2006), p. 4.

  55. 55.

    D. C. North , “Institutions” in The Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 5, No. 1 (1991), p. 97.

  56. 56.

    A. Gerschenkron , Economic backwardness (Cambridge, 1962), p. 31.

  57. 57.

    See, for example, A. Greif , Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade (Cambridge, 2006); D. North et al., Violence and social orders (Cambridge, 2009); D. Acemoglu and J. A. Robinson , Why Nations Fail (London, 2012).

  58. 58.

    F. Sejersted, Demokratisk kapitalisme (Oslo, 1993), p. 46.

  59. 59.

    F. Hodne and O. H. Grytten, Norsk økonomi i det nittende århundre (Bergen, 2000), p. 13.

  60. 60.

    M. Bakwena, “Do Better Institutions Alleviate the Resource Curse? Evidence from a Dynamic Panel Approach”, PhD Thesis, The University of Queensland Publication (April 2010). See also M. Bakwena, P. Bodman, T. Le and T. Ki, “Avoiding the Resource Curse: The Role of Institutions” University of Queensland, Australia, No 32, (2009) MRG Discussion Paper Series from School of Economics, University of Queensland, Australia; A. Cabrales and E. Hauk. “The quality of political institutions and the curse of natural resources”, The Economic Journal, 121 (February 2009).

  61. 61.

    R. Arezki, R. and M. Bruckner, “Resource Windfalls and Emerging Market Sovereign Bond Spreads: The Role of Political Institutions”, University of Adelaide, School of Economics, Research Paper No. 2011-08 (January 2011).

  62. 62.

    H. Mehlum, K. Moene and R. Torvik, “Cursed by resources or institutions?” (Oslo, 2005), p. 1.

  63. 63.

    Bhattacharyya, Sambit and Roland Hodler. “Natural Resources, Democracy and Corruption”. OxCarre Research Paper, No. 2009-20 (2009).

  64. 64.

    D. Acemoglu and J. A. Robinson , Why Nations Fail (London, 2012), p. 43.

  65. 65.

    D. Acemoglu and J. A. Robinson , Why Nations Fail (London, 2012), pp. 429–430.

  66. 66.

    A. Milward and S. B. Saul’s work is a rare exception to this. See The Economic Development of Continental Europe, 1780–1870 (London, 1973) and The Development of the Economies of Continental Europe (London, 1977).

  67. 67.

    For the importance of secure property rights in a historical perspective, see D. North et al., Violence and social orders (Cambridge, 2009) and A. Greif , Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade (Cambridge, 2006).

  68. 68.

    P. David , G. and Wright , “Increasing Returns and the Genesis of American Resource Abundance”, Oxford Journals, vol. 6, issue 2 (1997), pp. 210–218.

  69. 69.

    W. W. Culver and C. J. Reinhart “Capital dreams: Chile’s Response to Nineteenth-Century World Copper Competition”, Comparative Studies in Society and History, vol. 31, No. 4 (October 1989), p. 739.

  70. 70.

    K. Bruland , British technology and European industrialization (Cambridge, 1989), p. 15.

  71. 71.

    R. Falvey and N. Foster, “The Role of Intellectual Property Rights in Technology Transfer and Economic Growth: Theory and Evidence” (Vienna, 2006), p. vii.

  72. 72.

    B. L. Basberg, “Patenting and Early Industrialization in Norway, 1860–1914. Was there a Linkage?”, Scandinavian Economic History Review, vol. 54, Issue 1 (2006), p. 14.

  73. 73.

    J. Mokyr , “Intellectual property rights, the Industrial Revolution, and the Beginnings of Modern Economic Growth”, American Economic Review, vol. 99, issue 2 (2009), p. 351.

  74. 74.

    K. Bruland and K. Smith , “Knowledge Flows and Catching-Up Industrialization in the Nordic Countries: The Roles of Patent Systems”, in H. Odagiri et al. Intellectual property rights, development and catch-up an International comparative study (Oxford, 2010), pp. 63–94.

  75. 75.

    A. Breitwieser and N. Foster, “Intellectual property rights, innovation and technology transfer: a survey”, (Vienna, 2012), p. 2.

  76. 76.

    D. Acemoglu and J. A. Robinson , Why Nations Fail (London, 2012), p. 430.

  77. 77.

    D. North , “Violence and social orders”, The annual proceedings of the Wealth and Well-Being of Nations (2009), p. 22.

  78. 78.

    D. North , “A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history”, George Mason University, working paper 75 (Cambridge, 2006), pp. 3–4.

  79. 79.

    C. Edquist, “The Systems of Innovation Approach and Innovation Policy: An account of the state of the art” (Aalborg, 2001), p. 2.

  80. 80.

    See R. R. Nelson , R. R. National Innovation Systems A Comparative Analysis (New York, 1993).

  81. 81.

    C. Edquist , “The Systems of Innovation Approach and Innovation Policy: An account of the state of the art” (Aalborg, 2001), p. 3.

  82. 82.

    H. Hirsch-Kreinsen et al., “Low-Tech Industries and the Knowledge Economy: State of the Art and Research Challenges”, PILOT Policy and Innovation in Low-Tech, STEP – Centre for Innovation Research (Oslo, 2003), p. 9.

  83. 83.

    C. Edquist , “The Systems of Innovation Approach and Innovation Policy: An account of the state of the art” (Aalborg, 2001) p. 3.

  84. 84.

    G. S. Becker , Human Capital (New York, 1975), pp. 19–37.

  85. 85.

    K. Bruland , “Education” in Oxford encyclopedia of economic history, vol. II (Oxford, 2003), pp. 161–162.

  86. 86.

    N. Petrovsky, “Does Natural Resource Wealth Spoil and Corrupt Governments? A New Test of the Resource Curse Thesis”, thesis, August 2004; Denton, Texas.

  87. 87.

    M. Smart, “Natural Resource Diversity and Democracy”, The Economic Society of Australia, vol. 28 (December 2009), pp. 366–375.

  88. 88.

    S. M. Brooks and M. Kurtz, “Conditioning the “Resource Curse”: Globalization, Human Capital, and Growth in Oil-Rich Nations”, Comparative Political Studies, 44(6), (March 2011).

  89. 89.

    R. U. Mendoza, H. J. McArthur and A. O. Lopez, “Devil’s Excrement or Manna from Heaven? A Survey of Strategies in Natural Resource Wealth Management”, Asian Institute of Management Working Paper, 25 April 2012, p. 8.

  90. 90.

    G. B. Havro, and J. Santiso, “Rescuing the Resource Rich: How Can International Development Policy Help Tame the Resource Curse?” Working Paper Series, June 2010.

  91. 91.

    P. Lundgreen, “Engineering Education in Europe and the U.S.A., 1750–1930: The Rise to Dominance of School Culture and the Engineering Professions”, Annals of Science, vol. 47, Issue 1 (1990), pp. 33–75.

  92. 92.

    G. Ahlström , “Technical Competence and Industrial Growth”, Lund Papers in Economic History, No. 14, (1992), p. 1.

  93. 93.

    G. Ahlström , Engineers and Industrial Growth (London & Canberra, 1982), p. 94.

  94. 94.

    G. Ahlström , Engineers and Industrial Growth (London & Canberra, 1982); R. Fox, A. Guagnini, Education, technology, and industrial performance in Europe, 1850–1939 (Cambridge, 1993); G. W. Roderick and M. D. Stephens, Scientific and Technical Education in Nineteenth-Century England (Newton Abbot, 1972).

  95. 95.

    M. Sanderson, The Missing Stratum Technical School Education in England 1900–1990s (London, 1994), p. 145.

  96. 96.

    P. David , G. and Wright , “Increasing Returns and the Genesis of American Resource Abundance”, Oxford Journals, vol. 6, issue 2 (1997), pp. 231–234.

  97. 97.

    R. A. Easterlin , “Why Isn’t the Whole World Developed?”, Journal of Economic History, Vol. 41, Issue 1 (1981), p. 7.

  98. 98.

    P. Sandberg, “Ignorance, Poverty and Economic Backwardness in the Early Stages of European Industrialization: Variations on Alexander Gerschenkron’s Grand Theme”, Journal of economic history, vol. 11 (1982).

  99. 99.

    P. Sandberg, “The Case of the Impoverished Sophisticate: Human Capital and Swedish Economic Growth Before World War 1”, Journal of Economic History, vol. 49, No. 1 (1979), pp. 225–241.

  100. 100.

    J. Mokyr , “Knowledge, Enlightenment, and the Industrial Revolution: Reflections on Gifts of Athena, History of Science, vol. 45, part 2, (June 2006), p. 1.

  101. 101.

    C. M. Cipolla, Literacy and Development in the West (Baltimore, 1969), p. 114.

  102. 102.

    J. Mokyr , Gifts of Athena, (Princeton and Oxford, 2005), p. 292.

  103. 103.

    K. O’Rourke and J. Williamson , “Education, Globalization and Catch-Up: Scandinavia in the Swedish Mirror”, Scandinavian Economic History Review, XLIII, 3 (1995), p. 309.

  104. 104.

    P. Lundgreen “Engineering Education in Europe and the U.S.A., 1750–1930: The Rise to Dominance of School Culture and the Engineering Professions”, Annals of Science, 47, 1990, p. 34.

  105. 105.

    M. Spence, “Job Market Signaling”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 87, No. 3 (1973), pp. 335–374.

  106. 106.

    G. Ahlstrøm, “Technical education, engineering, and industrial growth: Sweden in the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries” in R. Fox, A. Guagnini, Education, technology, and industrial performance in Europe, 1850–1939 (Cambridge, 1993), p. 122.

  107. 107.

    G. W. Roderick and M. D. Stephens, Scientific and Technical Education in Nineteenth-Century England, (Newton Abbot, 1972), p. 16.

  108. 108.

    D. De Ferranti et al. From Natural Resources to the Knowledge Economy (Washington, DC, 2002), pp. 58–59.

  109. 109.

    W. F. Maloney, “Missed Opportunities: Innovation and Resource-Based Growth in Latin America”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2935 (2002), 37.

  110. 110.

    See W. F. Maloney, “Missed Opportunities: Innovation and Resource-Based Growth in Latin America”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2935 (2002); F. Valencia Caicedo and W. F. Maloney, “Engineers, Innovative Capacity and Development in the Americas”, Policy Research working paper; no. WPS 6814. Washington, DC: World Bank Group (2014).

  111. 111.

    R. R. Locke, The End of the Practical Man (London, 1984), p. 2.

  112. 112.

    R. R. Locke, The End of the Practical Man (London, 1984), p. 5.

  113. 113.

    W. Kőnig, “Technical education and industrial performance in Germany: a triumph of heterogeneity”, Education, Technology and Industrial Performance in Europe, 1850–1939, in R. Fox and A. Guagnini (eds) (Cambridge, 1993), p. 81.

  114. 114.

    SSB, Nasjonalregnskap 1900–1929; Statistisk sentralbyrå, Nasjonalregnskap 1930–1939 and 1946–1951.

  115. 115.

    C. Edquist , “The Systems of Innovation Approach and Innovation Policy: An account of the state of the art” (Aalborg, 2001), p. 3.

  116. 116.

    K. Bruland and K. Smith , “Knowledge Flows and Catching-Up Industrialization in the Nordic Countries: The Roles of Patent Systems”, in H. Odagiri et al. Intellectual property rights, development and catch-up an International comparative study (Oxford, 2010), pp. 63–94.

  117. 117.

    See, for instance, J. Mokyr , Gifts of Athena, (Princeton and Oxford, 2005); J. Mokyr , The Enlightened Economy (New Haven, 2009); K. Bruland , “Kunnskapsinstitusjoner og skandinavisk industrialisering” in Demokratisk konservatisme, Engelstad, F. and Sejersted, F. (eds.) (Oslo, 2006); K. Bruland, “Skills, learning and the International Diffusion of Technology: a Perspective on Scandinavian Industrialization”, in Technological Revolutions in Europe, M. Berg and K. Bruland (eds.) (Cheltenham, 1998); K. Bruland and K. Smith, “Knowledge Flows and Catching-Up Industrialization in the Nordic Countries: The Roles of Patent Systems”, in Intellectual property rights, development and catch-up an International comparative study, H. Odagiri et al. (Oxford, 2010), pp. 63–94; P. O’Brien , Stages in the Evolution of a Western regime for the discovery, development and diffusion of useful and reliable knowledge, URKEW Discussion Paper No. 7, London School of Economics (2011).

  118. 118.

    J. Mokyr , Gifts of Athena (Princeton and Oxford, 2005), p. 102.

  119. 119.

    K. Bruland and K. Smith , “Knowledge Flows and Catching-Up Industrialization in the Nordic Countries The Roles of Patent Systems”, in H. Odagiri et al. Intellectual property rights, development and catch-up an International comparative study (Oxford, 2010), pp. 63–94; K. Bruland, “Skills, learning and the International Diffusion of Technology: a Perspective on Scandinavian Industrialization”, in M. Berg and K. Bruland (eds.), Technological Revolutions in Europe (Cheltenham, 1998), p. 177.

  120. 120.

    P. Sandberg, “The Case of the Impoverished Sophisticate: Human Capital and Swedish Economic Growth Before World War 1”, Journal of Economic History, vol. 49, No. 1 (1979), pp. 225–241.

  121. 121.

    P. Musgrave, Technical Change, the Labour Force and Education (Oxford, New York, 1967), p. 27.

  122. 122.

    See J. Mokyr, “Knowledge, Enlightenment, and the Industrial Revolution: Reflections on Gifts of Athena”, History of Science, vol. 45, part 2, (June 2006).

  123. 123.

    K. Bruland , “Skills, learning and the International Diffusion of Technology: a Perspective on Scandinavian Industrialization”, in M. Berg and K. Bruland (eds.), Technological Revolutions in Europe (Cheltenham, 1998), p. 182.

  124. 124.

    K. Bruland and K. Smith , “Knowledge Flows and Catching-Up Industrialization in the Nordic Countries: The Roles of Patent Systems”, in H. Odagiri et al. Intellectual property rights, development and catch-up an International comparative study (Oxford, 2010), pp. 63–94.

  125. 125.

    G. Ahlström , Technological Development and Industrial Exhibitions 1850–1914 (Lund, 1995), p. 11.

  126. 126.

    K. Bruland , “Norsk mekanisk verkstedindustri og teknologioverføring 1840–1900”, in Teknologi i virksomhet: verkstedindustri i Norge etter 1840, E. Lange (ed.) (Oslo, 1989), pp. 46–47; K. Bruland, British technology and European industrialization (Cambridge, 1989).

  127. 127.

    P-O. Grönberg, Learning and Returning. Return Migration of Swedish Engineers from the United States, 1880–1940 (Sweden, 2003), p. 1.

  128. 128.

    Edward Glaeser, Thinkers and Tinkerers, History, New Republic, 22 June 2010.

  129. 129.

    See N. Craft, “Explaining the first Industrial Revolution: two views”, European Review of Economic History, vol. 15 (1), 2011; C. Edquist , “The Systems of Innovation Approach and Innovation Policy: An account of the state of the art” (Aalborg, 2001); K. Bruland, British technology and European industrialization (Cambridge, 1989).

  130. 130.

    H. Carstens, …Bygger i Berge: en beretning om norsk bergverksdrift (Trondheim, 2000), 10.

  131. 131.

    Statistisk sentralbyrå, Norges offisielle statistikk, Norges Bergverksdrift (Oslo, 1866–1940).

  132. 132.

    K. Bruland and D. C. Mowery, “Technology and the spread of capitalism”, in Cambridge History of Capitalism, vol. II, L. O’Neil and J. G. Williamson (Cambridge, 2014), 84.

  133. 133.

    R. R. Nelson , “Innovation”, in International Encyclopedia of social sciences 7 (1968), pp. 339–345.

  134. 134.

    D. Kline and N. Rosenberg , “An Overview of Innovation”, in R. Landau and N. Rosenberg (eds.) The Positive Sum Strategy: Harnessing Technology for Economic Growth (Washington, DC, 1986), p. 279.

  135. 135.

    D. Kline and N. Rosenberg , “An Overview of Innovation”, in R. Landau and N. Rosenberg (eds.) The Positive Sum Strategy: Harnessing Technology for Economic Growth (Washington, DC, 1986), p. 275.

  136. 136.

    K. Bruland and D. C. Mowery, “Technology and the spread of capitalism”, in Cambridge History of Capitalism, vol. II, L. O’Neil and J. G. Williamson (Cambridge, 2014), p. 84.

  137. 137.

    K. Bruland , British technology and European industrialization (Cambridge, 1989).

  138. 138.

    K. Bruland , “Norsk mekanisk verkstedindustri og teknologioverføring 1840–1900”, in Teknologi i virksomhet: verkstedindustri i Norge etter 1840, E. Lange (ed.) (Oslo, 1989), p. 34.

  139. 139.

    D. C. North , “Institutions” in The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 5, No. 1, (1991), p. 97.

  140. 140.

    J. Mokyr , Gifts of Athena, (Princeton and Oxford, 2005); J. Mokyr, The Enlightened Economy (New Haven, 2009), K. Bruland, “Kunnskapsinstitusjoner og skandinavisk industrialisering” in Demokratisk konservatisme, Engelstad, F. and Sejersted, F. (eds.) (Oslo, 2006); K. Bruland, “Skills, learning and the International Diffusion of Technology: a Perspective on Scandinavian Industrialization”, in M. Berg and K. Bruland (eds.), Technological Revolutions in Europe (Cheltenham, 1998).

  141. 141.

    K. J. Arrow, “The economic implications of learning by doing”, The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 29, No. 3 (1962), p. 155.

  142. 142.

    J. Mokyr , Gifts of Athena, (Princeton and Oxford, 2005), p. 73.

  143. 143.

    M. Polanyi , The Tacit Dimension (Gloucester, 1983), p. 4.

  144. 144.

    R. R. Nelson and S. G. Winter, An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change (Cambridge, 1982), p. 73.

  145. 145.

    J. Mokyr , “Knowledge, Enlightenment, and the Industrial Revolution: Reflections on Gifts of Athena, History of Science, vol. 45, part 2, (June 2006), pp. 1–2.

  146. 146.

    G. S. Becker , Human Capital (New York, 1975), p. 37.

  147. 147.

    R. R. Nelson and S. G. Winter, An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change (Cambridge, 1982), p. 78.

  148. 148.

    M. Polanyi , M. The Tacit Dimension (Gloucester, 1983), p. 13.

  149. 149.

    K. J. Arrow, “The economic implications of learning by doing”, The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 29, No. 3 (1962).

Bibliography

Secondary Sources (Literature)

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2012). Why Nations Fail. London: Profile Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ahlström, G. (1982). Engineers and Industrial Growth. London/Canberra: CROOM HELM.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ahlström, G. (1992). Technical Competence and Industrial Growth. Lund Papers in Economic History, No. 14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ahlström, G. (1995). Technological Development and Industrial Exhibitions 1850–1914. Lund: Lund University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andersen, A. D. (2012). Towards a New Approach to Natural Resources and Development: The Role of Learning, Innovation and Linkage Dynamics. International Journal of Technological Learning, Innovation and Development, 5(3), 291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrade, S., & Morales, J. (2007). The Role of the Natural Resource Curse in Preventing Development in Politically Unstable Countries: Case Studies of Angola and Bolivia. Institute for Advanced Development Studies, Development Research Working Paper Series No. 11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arezki, R., & Bruckner, M. (2011). Resource Windfalls and Emerging Market Sovereign Bond Spreads: The Role of Political Institutions. Research Paper No. 2011-08. Australia: University of Adelaide, School of Economics.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1962). The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing. The Review of Economic Studies, 29(3).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bakwena, M. (2010). Do Better Institutions Alleviate the Resource Curse? Evidence from a Dynamic Panel Approach, PhD Thesis. Queensland: The University of Queensland Publication.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bakwena, M., et al. (2009). Avoiding the Resource Curse: The Role of Institutions. MRG Discussion Paper Series from School of Economics, University of Queensland, Australia No. 32. Australia: University of Queensland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Basberg, B. L. (2006). Patenting and Early Industrialization in Norway, 1860–1914. Was There a Linkage? Scandinavian Economic History Review, 54(1), 4.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1975). Human Capital. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berg, M., & Bruland, K. (Eds.). (1998). Technological Revolutions in Europe. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergh, T., et al. (1983). Norge fra u-land til i-land: vekst og utviklingslinjer 1830–1980. Oslo: Gyldendal.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharyya, S., & Hodler, R. (2009). Natural Resources, Democracy and Corruption. OxCarre Research Paper, No. 2009-20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blomström, M., & Meller, P. (Eds.). (1991). Diverging Paths Comparing a Century of Scandinavian and Latin American Economic Development. Washington, DC: Johns Hopkins.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breitwieser, A., & Foster, N. (2012). Intellectual Property Rights, Innovation and Technology Transfer: A Survey. The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies Working Papers, 88.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brooks, S. M., & Kurtz, M. (2011). Conditioning the “Resource Curse”: Globalization, Human Capital, and Growth in Oil-Rich Nations. Comparative Political Studies, 44(6), 747–770.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruland, K. (1989). British Technology and European Industrialization. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cabrales, A., & Hauk, E. (2009). The Quality of Political Institutions and the Curse of Natural Resources. The Economic Journal, 121, 58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caicedo, F. V., & Maloney, W. F. (2014). Engineers, Innovative Capacity and Development in the Americas. Policy Research Working Paper; No. WPS 6814. Washington, DC: World Bank Group.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carstens, H. (2000). …Bygger i Berge: en beretning om norsk bergverksdrift. Trondheim: Norsk bergindustriforening Den norske bergingeniørforening Tapir.

    Google Scholar 

  • CEDA. (2007, July). Competing from Australia, No. 58. Melbourne: Committee for Economic Development of Australia.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cipolla, C. M. (1969). Literacy and Development in the West. Baltimore: Penguin Books Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Collier P., & Hoeffler, A. (2004). Greed and Grievance in Civil Wars. Oxford Economic Papers, 56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Craft, N. (2011). Explaining the First Industrial Revolution: Two Views. European Review of Economic History, 15, 1.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Culver, W. W., & Reinhart, C. J. (1989). Capital Dreams: Chile’s Response to Nineteenth-Century World Copper Competition. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 31(4), 722.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • David, P., & Wright, G. (1997). Increasing Returns and the Genesis of American Resource Abundance. Industrial and Corporate Change, 6(2), 203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Ferranti, D., et al. (2002). From Natural Resources to the Knowledge Economy. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. A. (1981). Why Isn’t the Whole World Developed? Journal of Economic History, 41(1), 1.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edquist, C. (2001, June 12–15). The Systems of Innovation Approach and Innovation Policy: An Account of the State of the Art. Lead Paper Presented at the DRUID Conference, Aalborg.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eicher, T., & Turnovsky, S. (Eds.). (2003). Inequality and Growth: Theory and Policy Implications. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fagerberg, J., et al. (2008, June). Innovation-Systems, Path-Dependency and Policy: The Co-evolution of Science, Technology and Innovation Policy and Industrial Structure in a Small, Resource-Based Economy. Working Papers on Innovation Studies 20080624, Centre for Technology, Innovation and Culture, University of Oslo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Falvey, R., & Foster, N. (2006). The Role of Intellectual Property Rights in Technology Transfer and Economic Growth: Theory and Evidence. Vienna: United Nations Industrial Development Organization.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fosu, A. K. (2013). Development Success: Historical Accounts from More Advanced Countries. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fox, R., & Guagnini, A. (1993). Education, Technology, and Industrial Performance in Europe, 1850–1939. Cambridge: University of Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, J. A. (2010). The Natural Resource Curse: A Survey. NBER Working Paper 15836.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerschenkron, A. (1962). Economic Backwardness. Cambridge: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E. (2010, June 22). Thinkers and Tinkerers. History, New Republic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A. (2006). Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Grönberg, P.-O. (2003). Learning and Returning. Return Migration of Swedish Engineers from the United States, 1880–1940. PhD Thesis. Sweden: Umeå University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gylfason, T. (2001). Natural Resources, Education and Economic Development. European Economic Review, 45, 847.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Havro, G. B., & Santiso, J. (2010, June). Rescuing the Resource Rich: How Can International Development Policy Help Tame the Resource Curse? ESADE Knowledge, Working Paper Series.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirsch-Kreinsen, H., et al. (2003). Low-Tech Industries and the Knowledge Economy: State of the Art and Research Challenges. In PILOT Policy and Innovation in Low-Tech. Oslo: STEP – Centre for Innovation Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodne, F., & Grytten, O. H. (2000). Norsk økonomi i det nittende århundre. Bergen: Fagbokforlaget.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karl, T. L. (1997). The Paradox of Plenty. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuznets, S. (1965). Economic Growth and Structure. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landau, R., & Rosenberg, N. (Eds.). (1986). The Positive Sum Strategy: Harnessing Technology for Economic Growth. Washington, DC: National Academy Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lange, E. (Ed.). (1989). Teknologi i virksomhet: verkstedindustri i Norge etter 1840. Oslo: Ad notam forlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Larsen, E. R. (2003). Are Rich Countries Immune to the Resource Curse? Evidence from Norway’s Management of its Oil Riches. Discussion Paper 362 Statistics Norway.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lederman, D., & Maloney, W. (2007). Natural Resources: Neither Curse nor Destiny. Washington, DC/Palo Alto: World Bank/Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Locke, R. R. (1984). The End of the Practical Man. London: JAI Press Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundgreen, P. (1990). Engineering Education in Europe and the U.S.A, 1750–1930: The Rise to Dominance of School Culture and the Engineering Professions. Annals of Science, 47(1), 33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundvall, B.-Å. (1992). National Systems of Innovation. London: Pinter Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maloney, W. F. (2002). Missed Opportunities: Innovation and Resource-Based Growth in Latin America. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2935.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, W., & Mitra, D. (2001). Productivity Growth and Convergence in Agriculture and Manufacturing. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 49(2), 403–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehlum, H., Moene, K., & Torvik, R. (2005). Institutions and the Resource Curse. The Economic Journal, 116(508), 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mendoza, R. U., et al. (2012, April 25). Devil’s Excrement or Manna from Heaven? A Survey of Strategies in Natural Resource Wealth Management. Asian Institute of Management Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milward, A., & Saul, S. B. (1973). The Economic Development of Continental Europe, 1780–1870. London: Allen & Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milward, A., & Saul, S. B. (1977). The Development of the Economies of Continental Europe 1850–1914. London: Allen & Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (2005). Gifts of Athena. Princeton/Oxford: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (2006). Knowledge, Enlightenment, and the Industrial Revolution: Reflections on Gifts of Athena. History of Science, 45(part 2), 185.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (2009a). Intellectual Property Rights, the Industrial Revolution, and the Beginnings of Modern Economic Growth. American Economic Review, 99(2), 349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (2009b). The Enlightened Economy. An Economic History of Britain 1700–1850. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave, P. (1967). Technical Change the Labour Force and Education. Oxford/New York: Pergamon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R. (1968). Innovation. In International Encyclopedia of Social Sciences, 7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R. (1993). National Innovation Systems a Comparative Analysis. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, B., & Behar, A. (2008, February 7). Natural Resources, Growth and Spatially-Based Development: A View of the Literature. World Development Report, Reshaping Economic Geography.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. (1982). An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge: Belknap Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1955). Location Theory and Regional Economic Growth. Journal of Political Economy, 63, 243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1991). Institutions. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1), 97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1993). New Institutional Economics and Development. Washington, DC: Washington University.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1996). Economic Performance Through Time: The Limits to Knowledge. EconWPA, Economic History, 9612004.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (2006). A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History. George Mason University, Working Paper 75.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (2009a). Violence and Social Orders. The Annual Proceedings of the Wealth and Well-Being of Nations, Beloit.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (2009b). Violence and Social Orders. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nuur, C., & Laestadius, S. (2009). Anomalies in the Resource Curse Paradigm: The Case of Sweden. Trieta Research Report, The Royal Institute of Technology, KTH.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Brien, P. (2011). Stages in the Evolution of a Western Regime for the Discovery, Development and Diffusion of Useful and Reliable Knowledge. URKEW Discussion Paper No. 7, London School of Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Neal, L., & Williamson, J. G. (Eds.). (2014). Cambridge History of Capitalism (Vol. II). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Rourke, K. H., & Williamson, J. G. (1995). Education, Globalization and Catch-Up: Scandinavia in the Swedish Mirror. Scandinavian Economic History Review, 43(3), 287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Odagiri, H., et al. (2010). Intellectual Property Rights, Development and Catch-Up an International Comparative Study. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Oxford Encyclopedia of Economic History, Vol. II (2003): Cooperative Agriculture and Farmer Cooperatives. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Petrovsky, N. (2004). Does Natural Resource Wealth Spoil and Corrupt Governments? A New Test of the Resource Curse Thesis. University of North Texas.

    Google Scholar 

  • Polanyi, M. (1983). The Tacit Dimension. Gloucester: Peter Smith.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prebisch, R. (1950). The Economic Development of Latin America and Its Principal Problems. New York: United Nations.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roderick, G. W., & Stephens, M. D. (1972). Scientific and Technical Education in Nineteenth-Century England. Newton Abbot: David & Charles.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, J. D., & Warner, A. M. (2001). The Curse of Natural Resources. European Economic Review, 45, 4–6.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sæther, B., Isaksen, A., & Karlsen, A. (2011, June). Innovation by Co-evolution in Natural Resource Industries: The Norwegian Experience. Geoforum, 42(3), 373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandberg, P. (1979). The Case of the Impoverished Sophisticate: Human Capital and Swedish Economic Growth Before World War 1. Journal of Economic History, 49, 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandberg, L. (1982). Ignorance, Poverty and Economic Backwardness in the Early Stages of European Industrialization: Variations on Alexander Gerschenkron’s Grand Theme. Journal of European Economic History, 11, 675–697.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanderson, M. (1994). The Missing Stratum Technical School Education in England 1900–1990s. London: Athlone Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sejersted, F. (1993). Demokratisk kapitalisme. Oslo: Universitetsforlaget.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smart, M. (2009). Natural Resource Diversity and Democracy. The Economic Society of Australia, 28, 366.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spence, M. (1973). Job Market Signaling. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87(3), 355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Statistisk sentralbyrå (1866–1940): Norges offisielle statistikk, Norges Bergverksdrift. Oslo: Statistisk sentralbyrå.

    Google Scholar 

  • Statistisk Sentralbyrå. (1952). Norges Offisielle Statistikk, Nasjonalregnskap 1930–1939 og 1946–1951. Oslo: Statistisk Sentralbyrå.

    Google Scholar 

  • Statistisk Sentralbyrå. (1953). Norges Officielle Statistikk, Nasjonalregnskap 1900–1929. Oslo: Statistisk Sentralbyrå.

    Google Scholar 

  • Suslova, E., & Volchkova, N. (2007). Human Capital, Industrial Growth and Resource Curse. State University Higher School of Economics: WP 13/2007/11 CAS Working Paper Series.

    Google Scholar 

  • The Dutch Disease. (1977, November 26). The Economist.

    Google Scholar 

  • UNCTAD. (2001). World Investment Report 2001 Promoting Linkages. New York/Geneva: United Nations.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van der Ploeg, F. (2010). Natural Resources: Curse or Blessing? CESifo Working Paper No. 3125.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vernengo, M. (2006). Technology, Finance, and Dependency: Latin American Radical Political Economy in Retrospect. Review of Radical Political Economics, 38(4), 551.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ville, S., & Wicken, O. (2013, October 1). The Dynamics of Resource-Based Economic Development: Evidence from Australia and Norway. Industrial and Corporate Change, 22(5), 1341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viner, J. (1952, February). International Trade and Economic Development. Louvain Economic Review, 20(1).

    Google Scholar 

  • Wicken, O. (2010). The Norwegian Path Creating and Building Enabling Sectors. Working Paper, Centre for Technology, Innovation and Culture, University of Oslo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wrigley, E. A. (2010). Energy and the Industrial Revolution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

Web Pages

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Ranestad, K. (2018). Introduction. In: Knowledge-Based Growth in Natural Resource Intensive Economies. Palgrave Studies in Economic History. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-96412-6_1

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-96412-6_1

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-96411-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-96412-6

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics