Skip to main content

Using Simulated Reproductive History Data to Re-think the Relationship Between Education and Fertility

  • Conference paper
  • First Online:
Social Informatics (SocInfo 2019)

Part of the book series: Lecture Notes in Computer Science ((LNISA,volume 11864))

Included in the following conference series:

Abstract

The weakening negative educational gradient of fertility is usually interpreted as the expression of changes in the way education shapes reproductive decisions across cohorts. We argue, however, that the reversal of the statistical association does not imply a reversal in the underlying mechanisms that connect education and fertility. Instead, we believe the reversal in the statistical association emerges as a result of the convergence of the life-course of individuals with different educational attainment levels across two dimensions: the ability to control the reproductive process and the desire for a given family size. In order to show this we reproduce the results reported in previous studies by using simulated reproductive trajectories, generated from a model that assumes no change in the way education shapes reproductive intentions over time. Beyond our substantive focus, we intend to show how our understanding of key demographic processes could change if we were able to incorporate in our modeling difficult or impossible to observe quantities.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Italics in the original.

  2. 2.

    For the cohorts born after 1980 we extrapolate linearly from previous trends.

References

  1. Becker, G.S.: An economic analysis of fertility. In: Demographic and Economic Change in Developed Countries, pp. 209–240. Columbia University Press (1960)

    Google Scholar 

  2. Becker, G.S., Lewis, H.G.: On the interaction between the quantity and quality of children. J. Polit. Econ. 81(2, Part 2), S279–S288 (1973)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Becker, G.S., Tomes, N.: Child endowments and the quantity and quality of children. J. Polit. Econ. 84(4, Part 2), S143–S162 (1976)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Bongaarts, J.: The measurement of wanted fertility. Population Dev. Rev. 16, 487–506 (1990)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Bongaarts, J.: Trends in unwanted childbearing in the developing world. Stud. Fam. Planning 28, 267–277 (1997)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Bongaarts, J.: Fertility and reproductive preferences in post-transitional societies. Population Dev. Rev. 27, 260–281 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Bulatao, R.A., Lee, R.D., Hollerbach, P., Bongaarts, J.: Determinants of fertility in developing countries (1983)

    Google Scholar 

  8. Caltabiano, M., Castiglioni, M., Rosina, A., et al.: Lowest-low fertility: signs of a recovery in Italy. Demographic Res. 21(23), 681–718 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Castiglioni, M., Dalla Zuanna, G., Loghi, M.: Planned and unplanned births and conceptions in Italy, 1970–1995. Euro. J. Population/Rev. Européenne de Démographie 17(3), 207–233 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Ciganda, D., Todd, N.: Micro-level dynamics behind the recuperation of fertility at higher development levels. Max Planck Institute for Demographic Research Working Paper (2019)

    Google Scholar 

  11. Ciganda, D., Villavicencio, F.: Feedback mechanisms in the postponement of fertility in Spain. In: Grow, A., Van Bavel, J. (eds.) Agent-Based Modelling in Population Studies. TSSDMPA, vol. 41, pp. 405–435. Springer, Cham (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-32283-4_14

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  12. Cleland, J.: Marital fertility decline in developing countries: theories and the evidence (1985)

    Google Scholar 

  13. Cochrane, S.H.: Fertility and education: what do we really know? (1979)

    Google Scholar 

  14. Cochrane, S.H.: Effects of education and urbanization on fertility (1983)

    Google Scholar 

  15. De Wachter, D., Neels, K.: Educational differentials in fertility intentions and outcomes: family formation in flanders in the early 1990s. Vienna Yearb. Population Res. 9, 227–258 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Doepke, M.: Gary becker on the quantity and quality of children. J. Demographic Econ. 81(1), 59–66 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Easterlin, R.A., Crimmins, E.M.: The Fertility Revolution: A Supply-Demand Analysis. University of Chicago Press (1985)

    Google Scholar 

  18. Esping-Andersen, G.: Incomplete Revolution: Adapting Welfare States to Women’s New Roles. Polity, Cambridge (2009)

    Google Scholar 

  19. Grow, A., Schnor, C., Van Bavel, J.: The reversal of the gender gap in education and relative divorce risks: a matter of alternatives in partner choice? Population Stud. 71(Suppl. 1), 15–34 (2017)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Grow, A., Van Bavel, J.: Assortative mating and the reversal of gender inequality in education in Europe: an agent-based model. PloS One 10(6), e0127806 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Henshaw, S.K.: Unintended pregnancy in the united states. Fam. Plann. Perspect. 30, 24–46 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Hoem, B., Hoem, J.M.: The impact of women’s employment on second and third births in modern sweden. Population Stud. 43(1), 47–67 (1989)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Klijzing, E.: Are there unmet family planning needs in Europe? Fam. Plann. Perspect. 32, 74–88 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Kohler, H.P.: Fertility and Social Interaction: An Economic Perspective. Oxford University Press, Oxford (2001)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  25. Kohler, H.P., Billari, F.C., Ortega, J.A.: The emergence of lowest-low fertility in Europe during the 1990s. Population Dev. Rev. 28(4), 641–680 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Kravdal, Ø.: The emergence of a positive relation between education and third birth rates in Norway with supportive evidence from the united states. Population Stud. 46(3), 459–475 (1992)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Kravdal, Ø.: The high fertility of college educated women in Norway: an artefact of the separate modelling of each parity transition. Demographic Res. 5, 187–216 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Kravdal, Ø., Rindfuss, R.R.: Changing relationships between education and fertility: a study of women and men born 1940 to 1964. Am. Sociol. Rev. 73(5), 854–873 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Kreyenfeld, M.: Time-squeeze, partner effect or self-selection? An investigation into the positive effect of women’s education on second birth risks in west Germany. Demographic Res. 7, 15–48 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Luci-Greulich, A., Thévenon, O.: Does economic advancement ‘Cause’a re-increase in fertility? An empirical analysis for OECD countries (1960–2007). Eur. J. Population 30(2), 187–221 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Mencarini, L., Tanturri, M.L.: Time use, family role-set and childbearing among Italian working women. Genus 60, 111–137 (2004)

    Google Scholar 

  32. Mills, M., Mencarini, L., Tanturri, M.L., Begall, K.: Gender equity and fertility intentions in Italy and The Netherlands. Demographic Res. 18, 1–26 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Minnesota Population Center: Integrated public use microdata series, international: Version 7.0 (2018)

    Google Scholar 

  34. Montgomery, M.R., Casterline, J.B.: The diffusion of fertility control in Taiwan: evidence from pooled cross-section time-series models. Population Stud. 47(3), 457–479 (1993)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Murphy, M.: The contraceptive pill and women’s employment as factors in fertility change in britain 1963–1980: a challenge to the conventional view. Population Stud. 47(2), 221–243 (1993)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  36. Myrskylä, M., Kohler, H.P., Billari, F.C.: Advances in development reverse fertility declines. Nature 460(7256), 741–743 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Notestein, F.W.: Economic Problems of Population Change. Oxford University Press, London (1953)

    Google Scholar 

  38. Carreras de Odriozola, A., Tafunell Sambola, X.: Estadísticas históricas de España, siglos XIX-XX. Fundacion BBVA/BBVA Foundation (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  39. R Core Team: R: A Language and Environment for Statistical Computing. R Foundation for Statistical Computing, Vienna, Austria (2015). http://www.r-project.org

  40. Régnier-Loilier, A., Leridon, H., Cahen, F., et al.: Four decades of legalized contraception in France: an unfinished revolution? Technical report, Institut National d’Études Démographiques (INED) (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  41. Rindfuss, R.R., Bumpass, L., John, C.: Education and fertility: implications for the roles women occupy. Am. Sociol. Rev. 45(3), 431–447 (1980)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Rosero-Bixby, L., Casterline, J.B.: Modelling diffusion effects in fertility transition. Population Stud. 47(1), 147–167 (1993)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  43. Sullivan, O., Billari, F.C., Altintas, E.: Fathers’ changing contributions to child care and domestic work in very low-fertility countries: the effect of education. J. Fam. Issues 35(8), 1048–1065 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  44. Testa, M.R.: On the positive correlation between education and fertility intentions in Europe: individual-and country-level evidence. Adv. Life Course Res. 21, 28–42 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  45. Villa, P.: Séries macro-économiques historiques: méthodologie et analyse économique. Institut National de la Statistique et des Etudes Economiques (1997)

    Google Scholar 

  46. Willekens, F.: Continuous-time microsimulation in longitudinal analysis. In: New frontiers in microsimulation modelling, pp. 353–376 (2009)

    Google Scholar 

  47. Wulf, D.: Low fertility in Europe: a report from the 1981 IUSSP meeting. Fam. Plann. Perspect. 14(5), 264–270 (1982)

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Daniel Ciganda .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

A Appendix

A Appendix

1.1 A.1 Detailed Model Description

We use a discrete-event simulation approach in which time advances with the realization of each event. As shown in the pseudocode in Appendix A, at each iteration the algorithm realizes the event with the shortest waiting time from a list of all possible events for the entire population of agents. After the realization of each event the system is updated and the simulation continues to the next run.

We refer to the time between events as process (or duration) time t, which is expressed in seconds. Process time can be related to calendar time c which, as mentioned before, runs from the beginning of 1925 until the end of 2016. The third relevant duration in our model is Age x, which goes from 0 to 51, age at which our simulated individuals are removed from the population.

Desire Family Size: Known as the demand for children, the Desired Family Size (D) is the central quantity in classic microeconomic models of fertility, from the New Home Economics approach to Coale’s Ready Willing and Able framework, Easterlin’s supply-demand framework and its applications to developing countries [7].

In our model D does not represent an ideal number, but the answer a simulated woman would give to the question How many children do you want to have?.

Most explanations of the fertility transitions of the 1960s and 1970s in Europe have focused on the reduction of the demand for children as a consequence of the erosion of the conditions that led to the baby-boom, in particular the dominance of the male bread-winner paradigm following the rapid increase of women’s participation in the labor market [35]. In our model we try to capture this movement defining D as:

$$\begin{aligned} D_{i} \sim \varGamma _{a\le D_i \le b}({}_{0}D + \alpha - \beta ^{A_i}, 1) \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where \(A_{i} \in \{0,1\}\), is the labor force participation status of agent i (obtained from census data as explained in Sect. 7). Our computations based on the Integrated Value Surveys Database (not shown) confirmed our expectation that the distribution of family size preferences is positively skewed and justifies the choice of a Gamma distribution. The limits of the distribution a and b are the minimum and maximum number of desired children and the shape parameter is a function of \({}_{0}D\) (an initial value of D to be estimated) and parameters \(\alpha \) & \(\beta \), which define the distance between the distributions of D for active and inactive women. This distance expresses different preferences regarding the distribution of time between childrearing and other activities, but also the difficulties women expect to find when combining work and family.

Intentions: In our model the number of planned children people end up having is closely connected to their short term fertility intentions. Although there is a lengthy list of factors that could affect fertility intentions, here we necessarily have to focus on those most relevant to the context and periods we analyze, i.e., school enrollment status, perceived economic uncertainty, labor force participation status and educational attainment. Formally, the intention to have a child \({}_{B}I\) is defined as:

$$\begin{aligned} {}_{B}I_{i,x}= {}_{B}\rho _{i} - \varepsilon _{i,x} - R_c - \upsilon _{i} \end{aligned}$$
(2)

where \(\rho \) is the baseline intention which can be interpreted as the intention, free of constraints, to have a child for those agents who have the desire to have children (\(D > 0\)). We assume that \(\rho \) comes from a truncated normal distribution, which allows us to introduce some variation in fertility intentions that is not directly related to the set of factors listed above.

\(E_{i} \in \{0,1\}\) is the enrollment status of agent i and \(\varepsilon \) expresses the strength of the negative effect than being in the education system has over short-term fertility intentions.

R represents the perceived resources to afford a/an additional child and is given by a smoothed series of the unemployment rate, which we use to approximate the perception of agents regarding the economic situation at time c.

The last mechanism in 2 expresses the effect of education among working women and is defined as:

$$\begin{aligned} \upsilon _{i} = \eta / (1 + exp(\delta \cdot (Y_{i} - Y^*))) + (1 -\eta ) \end{aligned}$$
(3)

The mechanism is represented as a logistic function that moves from \(1- \eta \) to 1 as the number of years of education Y approaches the threshold \(Y^*\). The central idea here is that educational attainment helps to reduce the gap between working and non-working women with respect to short-term intentions as explained in Sect. 5.1.

From Intentions to Births: To connect intentions to births we assume that waiting times to the attempt to conceive are exponentially distributed with a rate proportional to the intention \({}_{B}I\).

This allows us to draw a waiting time for each woman with a partner who still has not achieved her desired family size. If the resulting waiting time is shorter than one year, at the end of that time our simulated couple will attempt to have a child, if it is longer they will update their intention after one year and reconsider whether or not to have a child within the next twelve months. These formulation allows us to introduce period effects in a discrete-event context that is in general better suited for the analysis of cohort processes.

We define the event as the attempt to conceive in order to be able to represent the decline in the probability to experience a pregnancy with age. This probability is defined as:

$$\begin{aligned} p_x=1 /1 + \exp (\theta (x - \omega )) \end{aligned}$$
(4)

where \(\omega \) controls the age at which the probability starts decreasing and it is assumed to be fixed for all agents.

If the couple fail to conceive, they will try again in a period of one to four months (draw from a truncated normal distribution with mean 1.5), until they reach a predefined limit for failed attempts. If they succeed, a waiting time equal 270 days is created which represents the duration of the pregnancy. After conception, if they still have not reached D they will go back to updating their intention/evaluating whether to try and have a new child after a period of ten to eighteen months (also drawn from a truncated normal distribution).

Unplanned Births: In our model, a couple that had already achieved their desired family size (including \(D = 0\)) still has a probability u to have an unplanned birth defined as:

$$\begin{aligned} u_{i,c} = \frac{\phi /(Y_{i}^\kappa )}{1 + e^{\iota \cdot (c-(c_{0}-Y_{i}))}} \end{aligned}$$
(5)

The use of a logistic function follows the representation of the adoption of contraception as a diffusion process [42]. As contraceptive methods become more effective the probability to have an unplanned birth declines. Parameters \(\iota \) and \(\psi \) control the pace of the decline and its inflection point. Besides, as the diffusion process is usually led by more educated women we also make u dependent on an agent’s educational attainment and let \(\kappa \) control the differences in the probability by years of education (Y).

Education Completion: The time agents take to complete their education depends on their level of education, which is determined by drawing a random number from 1 to 3 (representing the three educational levels considered) with probability equal to the observed proportions in each level by birth cohort.

After an education level is assigned the number of years \(Y_{i}\) agents will remain in the education system is obtained from a truncated normal distribution:

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{i}\sim N_{c\le Y_{i} \le d}(\mu , 3) \end{aligned}$$
(6)

where \(c=0\) and \(d=6\) for those with primary education or less; \(c=6\) and \(d=12\) for those with secondary education; \(c=12\) and \(d=24\) for those with tertiary education. The mean of the distribution \(\mu \) increases linearly throughout the period from 3 to 6, 8 to 12 and 16 to 22 years, for primary, secondary and tertiary education respectively. The waiting time to education \(_{E}T_{i}\) is then obtained by expressing \(Y_{i}\) in seconds.

Union Formation: The process that leads to the formation of a cohabiting union begins with the search for a partner. To define the dynamics of the search we adapt some ideas from previous marriage markets models [19, 20]. Women start searching for a partner around the time they complete their education. Once the time to select a partner arrives they choose among the pool of potential partners (composed by all men in the population born ten years before and three years after their own birth year) with a probability proportional to:

$$\begin{aligned} v_{ij} = \left( \frac{S_{max} - \left| s_i - s_j \right| }{S_{max}}\right) \cdot W_{j} \end{aligned}$$
(7)

where \(s_{i}\) represents her level of education and \(s_{j}\) his. Besides preferring partners that have similar levels of instruction we assume that women prefer partners that work over partners that do not. Therefore we define W as:

$$\begin{aligned} W_{j} = {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} 1, &{} \text {if } A_{j} = 1\\ 1/\tau , &{} \text {if }A_{j} = 0 \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(8)

After a woman chooses a partner they start a relationship and she develops an intention to form a union which is defined as:

$$\begin{aligned} {}_{U}I_{i,x}= {}_{U}\rho _{i} - \varepsilon ^{E_{i,x}} - R_c - U_x \end{aligned}$$
(9)

where \(U_x\) is a function of the proportion of a woman’s birth cohort that is already married at the time of updating \({}_{U}I\). The negative effect of \(U_x\) decreases as the proportion of married women increases, capturing the effects of social pressure. This mechanism generates a feedback that amplifies the effects of economic uncertainty and prolonged enrollment on the postponement of the age at union formation. It has been shown that these social multiplier effects are central to understand several sociodemographic processes like the spread of contraceptive use [34] and the postponement transition [11, 24].

As in the decision to have a child, \({}_{U}I\) is updated on a yearly basis until the simulated couple moves in together or one of them leaves the population.

Death. The waiting time to death \(_{D}T_{i}\) is sampled using the inverse distribution function method [46] where the distribution of waiting times to death is reconstructed using age-specific cohort mortality rates from the Human Mortality Database. For the ages/years where information is not available we use the latest available figures. Missing data corresponds essentially to the most recent decades, when mortality of females under 50 years of age is low.

1.2 A.2 Model Pseudo-Code

figure a

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this paper

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this paper

Ciganda, D., Lorenti, A. (2019). Using Simulated Reproductive History Data to Re-think the Relationship Between Education and Fertility. In: Weber, I., et al. Social Informatics. SocInfo 2019. Lecture Notes in Computer Science(), vol 11864. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-34971-4_15

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-34971-4_15

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-34970-7

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-34971-4

  • eBook Packages: Computer ScienceComputer Science (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics