Skip to main content

Still an Era of Fragmented Authoritarian 1.0? A Probabilistic Crucial Case Analysis

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 384 Accesses

Part of the book series: Politics and Development of Contemporary China ((PDCC))

Abstract

Now that the concepts of authoritarian institutions and dictator’s growth curse have been properly given corresponding interpretations in China’s political context, this chapter adopts a probabilistic crucial case analysis to determine the composition of China’s sectoral players in the trade policy game and justifies my choice of who should and should not be included in it. It is precisely because of the analysis in this chapter that it makes sense for the narratives to zero in on the Communist Party of China central committee members’ promotion expectations within the hierarchy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   59.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD   79.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    While the neologism of FA 2.0 coined by Mertha (2009) provides a nice way of labeling this string of literature on societal actors in policymaking processes, it has to be noted here that none of the other works cited above were explicitly written under this rubric. In a certain sense, however, this string of research is the culmination of the sociological turn in the China field that used to be dominated by studies on China’s high politics. More specifically, the works along this line not only study various aspects of China’s post-reform social dynamism, but, more importantly, also explore a variety of political ramifications of these aspects.

  2. 2.

    In fact, what Mertha (2009) means by “previously-excluded members” comprise those more than just societal actors and include “…officials only peripherally connected to the policy in question” (p. 996). However, as will be made clearer later, the analysis in this chapter mainly focuses on the distinction between government and societal actors.

  3. 3.

    The fact that China’s post-Tiananmen communist regime not only remains intact but is also gaining strength has given rise to a literature under the rubric of “resilient authoritarianism” (Nathan 2003).

  4. 4.

    Mertha (2009) lists two additional reasons for why this pluralistic transition is possible in China. First, China’s state actors find policy entrepreneurs’ expertise in their areas of interest useful. Second, there is a ratchet effect or positive path dependency by which one successful case of policy tinkering breeds another one.

  5. 5.

    See appendix for the exposition of the method of a probabilistic “crucial case” research design.

  6. 6.

    That is,

    $$ \mathit{\Pr}\left(\mathbf{Agency}\ \mathbf{Slac}{\mathbf{k}}_{\left\{i\right\}}\right)>\mathit{\Pr}\left(\mathbf{Agency}\ \mathbf{Slac}{\mathbf{k}}_{\mathrm{Mertha}}\right) $$
    (6.19)
  7. 7.
    $$ \mathit{\Pr}\left({h}_{\mathbf{FA}\ \mathbf{2.0}}^{\left\{i\right\}}\right)>\mathit{\Pr}\left({h}_{\mathbf{FA}\ \mathbf{2.0}}^{\mathrm{Mertha}}\right) $$
    (6.20)
  8. 8.

    Formally,

    $$ \mathit{\Pr}\left(\mathbf{Agency}\ \mathbf{Slac}{\mathbf{k}}_{\left\{i\right\}}\right)>\mathit{\Pr}\left(\mathbf{Agency}\ \mathbf{Slac}{\mathbf{k}}_{\mathrm{Kennedy}}|{e}^{\mathrm{Mertha}}\right) $$
    (6.21)
  9. 9.

    That is,

    $$ \frac{\mathit{\Pr}\left({h}_{\mathbf{FA}\ \mathbf{2.0}}^{\mathrm{Labor}}|{e}^{\mathrm{Kennedy}},{e}^{\mathrm{Mertha}}\right)}{\mathit{\Pr}\left({h}_{\mathbf{FA}\ \mathbf{2.0}}\right)}>1 $$
    (6.22)
  10. 10.

    The composition of the basket, however, is not made public.

  11. 11.

    Some of these policy changes were reversed later in 2008 owing to the untoward financial crisis. For instance, export tax rebates either canceled or cut in 2007 were raised again to help prevent export-dependent firms from going under.

  12. 12.

    Both Fig. 6.2 and Table 6.2 use data of the 66 sectors listed in Table 6.1.

  13. 13.

    While the graphs in Fig. 6.2 also show some outliers whose labor intensities are high while having low export dependency, the positive linear relationship in each year is hardly deniable.

  14. 14.

    One thing to be noted here is that our analysis essentially views the People’s Congress as a rubber stamp. As a result, while the passage of the Labor Contract Law has gone through a series of legislative processes that most policies are not subject to, the major gist of the Law was unaffected by the processes.

  15. 15.

    The popular perception that China’s exports account for 35% or 40% of its GDP is based on a problematic measure of dividing the value of exports by the GDP. This ratio, while floating around the major newspapers and even academic works, is tantamount to comparing apples to oranges since the GDP, the sum of value added by economic activities of a country’s residents, is not comparable to the value of exports, which is just a gross measure of revenues from exporting goods abroad. In other words, the figures computed this way improperly inflate the contribution of exports to China’s GDP. See Anderson (2007) for an adjusted estimate of how significant China’s exports really are to its GDP.

  16. 16.

    Labor Intensive Enterprises Go Under as Labor Cost Goes Up by 30% Due to the New Labor Law (Xi n Laodongfa zhi Chengben Zengsancheng Laodong Mijixin Qiye Chuju), Xi ngdao Daily 03.11.2008. Available at: http://www.stnn.cc/chinafin/200803/t20080311_745275.html.

  17. 17.

    While, according to the analytical framework developed in Hall (1993), the policy changes in 2007 were merely first-level, had it not been for the unexpected financial crisis taking place shortly after these changes were put in place, we would have seen a greater fundamental shift in China’s economic landscape.

  18. 18.

    Small-and-Medium-Sized Enterprises Are at the Life/Death Moment. Do the Central and the Guangdong Provincial Governments See Eye to Eye to Each Other? (Zhongxiao Qiye Shengsi Cunang Zhongyang Guangdong Geyou Kaoliang?), Xi ngdao Daily 11.19.2008. Available at: http://www.cnfstar.com/stock/2008/20081119/200811191092657.shtml.

  19. 19.

    Representatives Suggest to Experiment the Labor Contract Law First (Weiyuan Daibiao Jianyi Laodong Hetongfa Yingxian Shidian), Xi nxi Times 03.03.2008. Available at: http://finance.qq.com/a/20080303/000942.htm.

  20. 20.

    That is,

    $$ \frac{\mathit{\Pr}\left({h}_{\mathbf{FA}\ \mathbf{2.0}}^{\mathrm{Labor}}|{e}^{\mathrm{Labor}},{e}^{\mathrm{Kennedy}},{e}^{\mathrm{Mertha}}\right)}{\mathit{\Pr}\left({h}_{\mathbf{FA}\ \mathbf{2.0}}^{\mathrm{Labor}}|{e}^{\mathrm{Kennedy}},{e}^{\mathrm{Mertha}}\right)}<1 $$
    (6.23)
  21. 21.

    However, to the best of my knowledge, this Bayesian nature has not been treated formally in the literature, and therefore the understanding of the Bayesian properties of the crucial case method still remains “folkish” as it is provided in McKeown (1999).

  22. 22.

    Alternatively, if a ratio of them is taken, we are simply conducting the familiar likelihood ratio test in hypothesis testing. We will fully elaborate this point shortly.

  23. 23.

    When Eq. (6.11) = 0, \( h \) is simply irrelevant to the likelihood of \( e \).

  24. 24.

    The following explication of Eq. (6.12), however, focuses exclusively on the prior and the posterior because \( \mathit{\Pr}(e) \), the likelihood of \( e \), is determined by some probability distribution assumed exogenously.

  25. 25.

    For example, in Arend Lijphart’s (1968) classical (most-likely) crucial-case study on the Netherlands, the theory to be disconfirmed is the then poplar pluralist paradigm where reinforcing, as opposed to cross-cutting, social cleavages were viewed as the source of political instability. In this group of studies, countries are classified as having either reinforcing or cross-cutting cleavages, and the corresponding outcomes of interest are also dichotomized to be having either peaceful or conflictual regimes. According to this formulation, the Netherlands in Lijphart (1968) is a crucial case because it had reinforcing social cleavages while its political regime remained peaceful. The logic behind disconfirming the pluralist theory here is deterministic since if Lijphart (1968) is right (i.e., reinforcing cleavages \( \to \) peaceful regime), the opposite prediction by the pluralist theory (i.e., reinforcing cleavages \( \to \) conflictual regime) has no reason to hold for leading to a contradiction.

  26. 26.

    To make agency slack a continuous measure, we don’t necessarily have to conceptualize it as probabilities. Alternatively, it can also be viewed as a continuous variable with different levels of slack. The rationale for taking the probabilistic approach here is that while we don’t have a quantitative measure of agency slack, case studies can oftentimes give us a sense of which scenario is more likely to happen.

Bibliography

  • Anderson, Jonathan. 2007. Is China Export-Led? UBS Investment Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chou, Chia-Chen, and Han-Pu Tung. 2009. Crossing the River by Feeling the Stones? The Case of the Labor Contract Law in China. In Toward Better Governance in China: An Unconventional Pathway of Political Reform, ed. Baogang Guo and Dennis Hickey. Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooney, Sean, Sarah Biddulph, Kungang Li, and Ying Zhu. 2007. China’s New Labour Contract Law: Responding to the Growing Complexity of Labour Relations in the PRC. UNSW Law Journal 30 (3): 788–803.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deng, Guosheng, and Scott Kennedy. 2010. Business and Industry Association Lobbying in China: The Paradox of Contrasting Styles. China Journal 63: 101–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckstein, Harry. 1975. Case Study and Theory in Political Science. In Handbook of Political Science, ed. F.I. Greenstein and N.W. Polsby, vol. 7. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gallagher, Mary, and Jonathan Hanson. 2015. Power Tool or Dull Blade? Resilient Autocracy and the Selectorate Theory. Annual Review of Political Science 18: 367–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerring, John. 2007. Is There a (Viable) Crucial-Case Method. Comparative Political Studies 40 (3): 231–253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, Peter A. 1993. Policy Paradigms, Social Learning, and the State: The Case of Economic Policymaking in Britain. Comparative Politics 25 (3): 275–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heilmann, Sebastian. 2008. Policy Experimentation in China’s Economic Rise. Studies in Comparative International Development 43 (1): 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaufman, Robert R. 1986. Liberalization and Democratization in South America: Perspectives from the 1970s. In Transitions from Authoritarian Rule: Comparative Perspectives, ed. Guillermo O’Donnell, Philippe Schmitter, and Laurence Whitehead. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kennedy, Scott. 2005a. The Business of Lobbying in China. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2005b. China’s Porous Protectionism: The Changing Political Economy of Trade Policy. Political Science Quarterly 120 (3): 407–432.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy, Jack S. 2002. Qualitative Methods in International Relations. In Millennial Reflections on International Studies, ed. Michael Brecher and Frank P. Harvey. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lieberthal, Kenneth G. 1992. Introduction: The “Fragmented Authoritarianism” Model and Its Limitations. In Bureaucracy, Politics, and Decision Making in Post-Mao China, ed. Kenneth Lieberthal and David Lampton. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lieberthal, Kenneth G., and David Lampton. 1992. Bureaucracy, Politics, and Decision Making in Post-Mao China. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lieberthal, Kenneth G., and Michel Oksenberg. 1988. Policy Making in China: Leaders, Structures, and Processes. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, Arend. 1968. The Politics of Accommodation: Pluralism and Democracy in the Netherlands. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McKeown, Timothy J. 1999. Case Studies and the Statistical Worldview: Review of King, Keohane, and Verba’s Designing Social Inquiry: Scientific Inference in Qualitative Research. International Organization 53: 161–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mertha, Andrew C. 2008. China’s Water Warriors: Citizen Action and Policy Change. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2009. ‘Fragmented Authoritarianism 2.0’: Political Pluralization in the Chinese Policy Process. China Quarterly 200: 995–1012.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nathan, Andrew J. 2003. Authoritarian Resilience. Journal of Democracy 14 (1): 6–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ngok, Kinglun. 2008. The Changes of Chinese Labor Policy and Labor Legislation in the Context of Market Transition. International Labor and Working-Class History 73: 45–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pearson, Margaret M. 2005. The Business of Governing Business in China: Institutions and Norms of the Emerging Regulatory State. World Politics 57 (2): 296–322.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski, Adam. 1986. Some Problems in the Study of the Transition to Democracy. In Transitions from Authoritarian Rule: Comparative Perspectives, ed. Guillermo O’Donnell, Philippe Schmitter, and Laurence Whitehead. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, Robert D. 1993. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy with Robert Leonardi and Raffaella Y. Nanetti. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reilly, Benjamin, and Robert Phillpot. 2002. ‘Making Democracy Work’ in Papua New Guinea: Social Capital and Provincial Development in an Ethnically Fragmented Society. Asian Survey 42 (6): 906–927.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitter, Philippe C. 1974. Still the Century of Corporatism? Review of Politics 36 (1): 85–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, Jonathan. 2004. Environmental NGOs in China: Roles and Limits. Pacific Affairs 77 (1): 28–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sekhon, Jasjeet S. 2004. Quality Meets Quantity: Case Studies, Conditional Probability, and Counterfactuals. Perspectives on Politics 2 (2): 281–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shirk, Susan L. 1993. The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Westman, John. 1985. Modern Dependency: A ‘Crucial Case’ Study of Brazilian Government Policy in the Minicomputer Industry. Studies in Comparative International Development 20 (2): 25–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • White, Gordon. 1987. The Politics of Economic Reform in Chinese Industry: The Introduction of the Labour Contract System. China Quarterly 111: 365–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xu, Hua, Yi Zeng, and Allen F. Anderson. 2005. Chinese NGOs in Action Against HIV/AIDS. Cell Research 15 (11–12): 914–918.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhu, Xufeng. 2008. Strategy of Chinese Policy Entrepreneurs in the Third Sector: Challenges of ‘Technical Infeasibility’. Policy Science 41: 315–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hans H. Tung .

Appendix: A Qualitative Research Design: Probabilistic “Crucial Case” Method and Bayesian Inference

Appendix: A Qualitative Research Design: Probabilistic “Crucial Case” Method and Bayesian Inference

Given the lack of systematic (linear) measures of agency slack and societal actors’ political activities in various policy areas, the testing of the FA 2.0 thesis, as a consequence, has to resort mainly to case study methods. However, it is beyond the scope of the book to conduct a comparative case study of different policy areas. Consequently, on the one hand, we sift out from the qualitative methodologists’ tool kit a single-case research design of Harry Eckstein’s crucial case method (1975) that provides such a possibility of making inference from a case that is “critical” either in the confirmatory or in the disconfirmatory sense. On the other hand, as suggested by Gerring (2007), realistically, the crucialness of a case is chiefly not a question of “either/or,” but one of degree. The following analysis therefore reformulates the crucial case method in Eckstein (1975) to switch the logic of inference from deterministic to probabilistic so we can assess how much more confidence will be gained from our analysis of the Labor Contract Law vis-à-vis the findings in the burgeoning literature based on the FA 2.0 thesis.

1.1 Crucial Case Analysis and Bayesian Inference

The analytical leverage of the crucial case method in making inferences is principally based on how “crucial” is defined. According to Eckstein (1975), a “crucial” case is one that “must closely fit a theory if one is to have confidence in the theory’s validity, or, conversely, must not fit equally well any rule contrary to that proposed” (p. 118). This statement reveals clearly why (causal) inferences can be made from a single case study. Cases differ in how much empirical support they can provide for a given theory of interest. In other words, it is more cost-efficient to focus on cases that are more informative in the sense of either confirming or disconfirming the proposed theory.

Moreover, it can be readily recognized that the logic of inference lying within this idea is Bayesian (McKeown 1999; Sekhon 2004).Footnote 21 In Bayesian terms, as Colin Howson and Peter Urbach put it (Gerring 2007, p. 234), the degree to which a hypothesis (denoted by \( h \)) derived from the theory of interest is confirmed or disconfirmed by a set of evidence or cases (denoted by \( e \)) is a function of the expressionFootnote 22

$$ \mathit{\Pr}(e|h)-\mathit{\Pr}(e) $$
(6.11)

which is essentially a difference between the likelihood of \( e \) when \( h \) is true and that when \( h \) is false. If \( h \) is true (false), then Eq. (6.11) is positive (non-positive).Footnote 23 Alternatively, applying Bayes’ theorem to Eq. (6.11) yields

$$ \mathit{\Pr}(e)\left[\frac{\mathit{\Pr}(h|e)}{\mathit{\Pr}(h)}-1\right] $$
(6.12)

which shows patently that the degree of confirmation or disconfirmation depends on three parameters: (1) \( \mathit{\Pr}(e) \), (2) \( \mathit{\Pr}(h) \) (prior), and (3) \( \mathit{\Pr}\left(h|e\right) \) (posterior).Footnote 24

More specifically, as far as confirmatory crucial cases are concerned, the degree of confirmation is negatively associated with the Bayesian prior—\( \mathit{\Pr}(h) \), that is, our (subjective) assessment of how likely it is that \( h \) holds before the evidence is examined—and this implies that, ceteris paribus, our confidence in confirming the theory is raised to a higher level when the hypothesized relationship for a certain case is more counterintuitive and less likely to happen. The probability for the theory to hold in a case is minimal if, except the variable of interest, the case has almost all the characteristics that run counter to the presence of the predicted relationship. For instance, in Reilly and Phillpot (2002), Papua New Guinea is selected as a confirmatory crucial case to test Robert Putnam’s social capital theory (1993) for its high degree of ethnic fragmentation. In other words, the prior probability for the hypothesis derived from the social capital theory to hold in Papua New Guinea, \( \mathit{\Pr}\left({h}_{\mathrm{social}\ \mathrm{capital}}^{\mathrm{Papua}}\right) \), is believed to be substantially low. As a consequence, if the democracy in Papua New Guinea does “work,” it implies that

$$ \frac{\mathit{\Pr}\left({h}_{\mathrm{social}\ \mathrm{capital}}^{\mathrm{Papua}}|{e}^{\mathrm{Papua}}\right)}{\mathit{\Pr}\left({h}_{\mathrm{social}\ \mathrm{capital}}^{\mathrm{Papua}}\right)}>1 $$
(6.13)

and therefore not only will Eq. (6.12) be positive, but our confidence in the social capital theory is also enhanced to a higher level than that based on other cases \( \left\{\sim i\right\} \) with higher \( \mathit{\Pr}\left({h}_{\mathrm{social}\ \mathrm{capital}}^{\left\{\sim i\right\}}\right) \).

Regarding disconfirmatory crucial cases, the degree of disconfirmation is, on the contrary, positively related to the prior \( \mathit{\Pr}(h) \). That is, ceteris paribus, we can be more confident in rejecting the theory of interest under the condition that the predicted relationship is more intuitive and very likely to happen. In Westman (1985), for example, the Brazilian minicomputer industry is the most likely case for the dependency theory because the Brazilian capital, private or public, was non-existent in this industry before 1977, and the technology was also entirely controlled by multinational corporations by then. In Bayesian terms, this implies that arguably the prior, \( \mathit{\Pr}\left({h}_{\mathrm{dependency}\ \mathrm{theory}}^{\mathrm{Brazil}}\right) \), is believed to be very high in this case. Nonetheless, despite these two typical signs of dependence, the Brazilian government and national firms were still able to gain control over the industry after the former launched a series of policies to develop its own minicomputer industry. In other words, updated with this Brazilian case, we actually become less confident about the validity of the dependency theory. Applying the same Bayesian framework to this example yields the following set of relationships,

$$ \frac{\mathit{\Pr}\left({h}_{\mathrm{dependency}\ \mathrm{theory}}^{\mathrm{Brazil}}|{e}^{\mathrm{Brazil}}\right)}{\mathit{\Pr}\left({h}_{\mathrm{dependency}\ \mathrm{theory}}^{\mathrm{Brazil}}\right)}<1 $$
(6.14)

which not only makes Eq. (6.12) negative, but also increases our confidence in disconfirming the dependency theory as opposed to other cases with lower priors. In Jack Levy’s words, the logic of inference in both confirmatory and disconfirmatory crucial case studies can be intuitively explained by what he calls “Sinatra inferences” (2002). That is, the confirmatory crucial case method follows a Sinatra inference: “If I can make it there, I can make it anywhere.” By contrast, as far as the disconfirmatory crucial case method is concerned, the inverse Sinatra inference is applied that “If I cannot make it there, I cannot make it anywhere.”

1.2 Probabilistic Crucial Case Analysis and Fragmented Authoritarianism

1.2.1 Operationalizing the FA 2.0 Thesis

To apply the crucial case design to our question of interest, the FA 2.0 thesis, I use Fig. 6.3 to present the test in schematic form. As mentioned in Sect. 6.1.2, the transition from FA 1.0 to FA 2.0 means more than just an increase in the number of players in the policy game; it also means a qualitative transformation. To operationalize this transition for the sake of our empirical testing, however, the following analysis still uses changes in the number of members taking part in the process as a way to capture the effect of this transformation.

Fig. 6.3
figure 3

Crucial case test and China’s fragmented authoritarianism

To denote all the actors in Fig. 6.3, we use their initial letters, and therefore the set of China’s policymakers, \( P \), is a subset of the full set, \( F \), that contains all actors in Fig. 6.3 as its members

$$ P\subseteq F=\left\{B,C,L,M,O,T\right\} $$
(6.15)

When \( P=F \), China’s policymaking is characterized by the highest degree of fragmentation (i.e., democracy). Under the same notation, the other extreme of \( P \) where only top leaders matter in the policymaking process then becomes a singleton \( P=\left\{T\right\} \) It would be absurd to set \( P=F \), since the Chinese government so far has offered no effective institutional channels for its citizens to get organized and voice their concerns over policies. Regarding the other extreme, according to the long tradition in the literature on China’s post-reform policymaking (Liebertha l and Oksenberg 1988; Liebertha l 1992; Shirk 1993), setting

$$ P=\left\{T\right\} $$
(6.16)

does not reflect China’s political reality, either. Instead, as visualized by Fig. 6.3, the theory of transition assumed by the FA 2.0 thesis predicts an evolution in China’s policymaking process from FA 1.0

$$ {P}^{V1}=\left\{L,M,T\right\} $$
(6.17)

to FA 2.0

$$ {P}^{V2}=\left\{B,C,L,M,T\right\} $$
(6.18)

when agency slack is present in a given policy area.

1.2.2 Probabilistic Crucial Case Framework

After operationalizing the FA 2.0 thesis, we also make it clear here that our crucial case analysis in this chapter relaxes the assumption of deterministic theory made in the bulk of the literature.Footnote 25 In other words, the key parameter of the FA 2.0 theory of transition, agency slack, will be treated as a continuous and probabilistic measure,Footnote 26 \( \mathit{\Pr}\left(\mathbf{Agency}\ \mathbf{Slack}\right) \) (i.e., how likely it is for agency slack to take place in a given policy area), instead of a dichotomous variable with two outcomes, presence or absence of agency slack. Similarly, the outcome of interest, \( {P}^{V1} \) and \( {P}^{V2} \), will also be transformed into a probabilistic continuous measure, \( \mathit{\Pr}\left({P}^{V2}\right) \) (i.e., how likely it is for the FA 2.0 thesis to hold and societal actors to be able to exercise influence over policymaking process). According to this reading of the theory, as Gerring suggests (2007, p. 238), a case is crucial not in terms of its quality, but its degree of crucialness.

Form a Bayesian perspective, the probabilistic reading of the theory of interest makes it more straightforward to understand the logic of inference according to which gaining or losing confidence for a theory is determined by how crucial the case under scrutiny is. To put this in the context of the FA 2.0 thesis, a case is more crucial, confirmatorily, when \( \mathit{\Pr}\left(\mathbf{Agency}\ \mathbf{Slac}{\mathbf{k}}_i\right) \) for policy area \( i \) is lower, since, as per the thesis, the expectation for the FA 2.0 thesis to hold under this circumstance is supposedly lower than it is when \( \mathit{\Pr}\left(\mathbf{Agency}\ \mathbf{Slac}{\mathbf{k}}_{\sim i}\right) \) is higher. More critically, the corollary of this is that our theoretical prior for policy area \( i \), \( \mathit{\Pr}\left({h}_{\mathbf{FA}\ \mathbf{2.0}}^i\right) \), will also be lower, and according to ([howurba2]), the resulting confidence in the theory of interest will increase when both the likelihood for the data (i.e., case), \( \mathit{\Pr}\left({e}^i\right) \), and the posterior, \( \mathit{\Pr}\left({h}_{\mathbf{FA}\ \mathbf{2.0}}^i|{e}^i\right) \), are held constant. Intuitively, when policy area \( i \) is less subject to agency slack, the FA 2.0 thesis is expected accordingly to be less likely to hold. As a result, the examination of policy area \( i \) can be much more rewarding in terms of our confidence in the validity of the thesis when the degree of policy tinkering is consistent with the theoretical prediction.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Tung, H.H. (2019). Still an Era of Fragmented Authoritarian 1.0? A Probabilistic Crucial Case Analysis. In: Economic Growth and Endogenous Authoritarian Institutions in Post-Reform China. Politics and Development of Contemporary China. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-04828-0_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics