Skip to main content
Log in

Equilibrium Illusion, Economic Complexity and Evolutionary Foundation in Economic Analysis

  • Article
  • Published:
Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

It is widely believed that an equilibrium framework based on simple models, such as the representative agent and bilateral bargaining, in a frictionless economy provides a consistent framework in micro, macro, finance, and institutional economics. However, equilibrium believes in self-stabilizing market and institutional convergence broken down when inherent instability and non-predictable uncertainty emerge under nonlinear and social interactions. Equilibrium illusions in economics and econometrics are pretty in math modeling but dangerous in policy decision. Known examples are the Frisch model of noise-driven cycles, the Lucas model of microfoundations, and the Coasian world of zero transactions. These models not only violate basic laws in science but also lack evidence in economic history. Their common problem is associated with linear Hamiltonian economics with symmetric information without history. Economies are dissipative systems in nature, characterized by symmetry breaking, information flow, a time arrow, and history. The many-body problem is fundamentally different from the one-body and two-body problem in mathematics. Both computational and natural experiments, such as a stock market crash and a transitional depression, reveal the severe limitations of equilibrium thinking and structural changes from evolutionary dynamics. The new science of complexity offers new tools of nonlinear dynamics and non-stationary time series analysis. Existing puzzles in equilibrium economics, such as persistent cycles, interruptive crises, market resilience, social movements, and organizational diversity, can be better understood by nonlinear dynamic models. Like the paradigm shift after Einstein in physics, the evolutionary perspective provides a general framework, while equilibrium models serve as its special cases, since the equilibrium picture is an approximation of economic complexity in a short-time window taken from a long-term historical current.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Arrow, K. J. (1962) “The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing,” Review of Economic Studies 39: 155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. and G. Debreu (1954) “Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy,” Econometrica 22. 3: 265–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barnett, W. A. and P. Chen (1988) “The Aggregation-Theoretic Monetary Aggregates Are Chaotic and Have Strange Attractors: An Econometric Application of Mathematical Chaos,” in W. Barnett, E. Berndt, and H. White (eds) Dynamic Econometric Modeling, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 199–246.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1991) “A Note on Restaurant Pricing and Other Examples of Social Influences on Price,” Journal of Political Economy 99: 1106–1116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black, F. and M. Scholes (1973) “The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities,” Journal of Political Economy 81: 637–654.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brillouin, L. (1962) Science and Information Theory, Academic Press, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvo, G. and F. Coricelli (1992) “Stabilizing a Previously Centrally Planned Economy: Poland 1990,” Economic Policy 14: 175–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carter, S. etalet al. (eds) (1997) Historical Statistics of the United States, Colonial Times to 1970 Bicentennial Edition, Cambridge University Press, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, P. (1987) “Origin of the Division of Labor and a Stochastic Mechanism of Differentiation,” European Journal of Operational Research 30: 246–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • - (1988) “Empirical and Theoretical Evidence of Monetary Chaos,” System Dynamics Review 4: 81–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • - (1996a) “A Random Walk or Color Chaos on the Stock Market?—Time-Frequency Analysis of Samp;P Indexes,” Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics amp; Econometrics 1.2: 87–103.

    Google Scholar 

  • - (1996b) “Trends, Shocks, Persistent Cycles in Evolving Economy: Business Cycle Measurement in Time-Frequency Representation,” in W. A. Barnett, A. P. Kirman, and M. Salmon (eds) Nonlinear Dynamics and Economics, Cambridge University Press, pp. 307–331.

    Google Scholar 

  • - (1999) The Frisch Model of Business Cycles-A Spurious Doctrine, But a Mysterious Success, IC 2 Working Paper 99-05-01, University of Texas at Austin.

    Google Scholar 

  • - (2002) “Microfoundations of Macroeconomic Fluctuations and the Laws of Probability Theory: the Principle of Large Numbers vs. Rational Expectations Arbitrage,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 49: 327–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • - (2005) “Evolutionary Economic Dynamics: Persistent Business Cycles, Disruptive Technology, and the Trade-Off between Stability and Complexity,” in K. Dopfer (ed) The Evolutionary Foundations of Economics, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 472–505.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • - (2006) “Market Instability and Economic Complexity: Theoretical Lessons from Transition Experiments,” in Y. Yao and L. Yueh (eds) Globalisation and Economic Growth in China World Scientific, Singapore, pp. 35–58.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • - (2007) “Complexity of Transaction Costs and Evolution of Corporate Governance,” Kyoto Economic Review 76. 2: 139–153.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheung, S. N. S. (1998) “The Transaction Costs Paradigm,” Economic Inquiry 36: 514–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1937) “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica 4.16: 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • - (1960) “The Problem of Social Cost,” Journal of Law and Economics 3.1: 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • - (1988) The Firm, the Market, and the Law, University of Chicago Press, Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Long, J. B., A. Shleifer, L. H. Summers and R. J. Waldmann (1990) “Positive Feedback Investment Strategies and Destabilizing Rational Speculation,” Journal of Finance 45. 2: 379–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dessing, M. (2002) “Labor Supply, the Family and Poverty: the S-shaped Labor Supply Curve,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 49. 4: 433–458.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dopfer, K. (2005) The Evolutionary Foundation of Economics, Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dornbusch, R. (1993) “The End of German Miracle,” Journal of Economic Literature 31.2: 881–885.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engle, R. F. and C. W. J. Granger (1987) “Co-integration and Error-correction: Representation, Estimation and Testing,” Econometrica 55: 251–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F. (1970) “Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work,” Journal of Finance 25: 384–433.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • - (1991) “Efficient Capital Market II,” Journal of Finance 46. 5: 1575–1617.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1953) “The Case of Flexible Exchange Rates,” in M. Friedman (ed) Essays in Positive Economics, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp. 157–203.

    Google Scholar 

  • - (1961) “The Lag in Effect of Monetary Policy,” Journal of Political Economy 69. 5: 447–466. [see page 454 on two choices of detrending; in M. Friedman (ed) (1969) Optimal Quantity of Money and Other Essays. Aldine, Chicago.]

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frisch, R. (1933) “Propagation Problems and Impulse Problems in Dynamic Economics,” in Economic Essays in Honour of Gustav Cassel, George Allen & Unwin, London, pp. 171–206.

    Google Scholar 

  • - (1981) “From Utopian Theory to Practical Applications: The Case of Econometrics,” American Economic Review 71. 6: 1–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galbraith, J. K. (2008) “Inequality, Unemployment and Growth: New Measurement for Old Controversies,” Journal of Economic Inequality (in press). [also see: University of Texas Inequality Project working paper (http://utip.gov.utexas.edu)]

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, P. and D. Soskice (2001) Varieties of Capitalism, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, G. D. and E. C. Prescott (2002) “Malthus to Solow,” American Economic Review 92. 4: 1205–1217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hao, B. L. (1990) Chaos II, World Scientific, Singapore.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1935) Prices and Production, Routledge, London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodrick, R. J. and E. C. Prescott (1997) “Post-War US. Business Cycles: An Empirical Investigation,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 29. 1: 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kolodko, G. W. (2000) From Shock to Therapy: The Political Economy of Postsocialist Transformation, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kornai, J. (1979) “Demand versus Resource Constrained Systems,” Econometrica 47.4: 801–819.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • - (1986) “The Soft Budget Constraints,” Kyklos 39. 1: 3–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kydland, F. E. and E. C. Prescott (1990) “Business Cycles: Real Facts and a Monetary Myth,” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 14: 3–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lentief, W. W. (1936) “The Fundamental Assumption of Mr. Keynes’ Monetary Theory of Unemployment,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 51: 192–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E. Jr. (1972) “Expectations and the Neutrality of Money,” Journal of Economic Theory, 4: 103–124. [also in Lucas (1981).]

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • - (1981) Studies in Business-Cycle Theory, MIT Press, MA: Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • - (1988) “On the Mechanics of Economic Development,” Journal of Monetary Economics 22: 3–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maddison, A. (2007) The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective/Historical Statistics, OECD: Development Center Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. (1920) Principles of Economics, 8th ed., Porcupine, Philadelphia.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minsky, H. P. (1985) “The Financial Instability Hypothesis: A Restatement,” in P. Arestis and T. Skouras (eds) Post Keynesian Economic Theory, Sharpe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Münter, M. and R. Sturm (2005) “Economic Consequences of German Unification,” in W. Gellner and J. D. Robertson (eds) Berlin Republic: German Unification and a Decade of Changes, Frank Cass, London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, C. R. and C. I. Plosser (1982) “Trends and Random Walks in Macroeconomic Time Series, Some Evidence and Implications,” Journal of Monetary Economics 10: 139–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • New Beijing News (2008) “China’s State Bank Reform under Central Bank: Costs 2.1 trillion Yuan, Generated Benefits 1 trillion Yuan in 4 years,” March 6, 2008) at: http://www.finance.sina.com.cn/roll/20080306/02062047268.shtml

    Google Scholar 

  • Prigogine, I. (1984) Order Out of Chaos, Bantam, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Qian, S. and D. Chen (1996) Joint Time-Frequency Analysis, Upper Saddle River Prentice-Hall, NJ.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, C. D. (2004) “Great Depression,” Encyclopedia Britannica, Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. M. (1986) “Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth,” Journal of Political Economy 94: 1002–1038.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross, S. (1976) “Return, Risk, and Arbitrage,” in I. Friend and J. Bicksler (eds) Risk and return in Finance, Ballinger, Cambridge, pp. 189–218.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rostow, W. W. (1960/1990) The Stages of Economic Growth, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • - (1978) The World Economy: History amp; Prospect, University of Texas Press, Austin, p. 675.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, J. D. (2005) The End of Poverty, Penguin Books, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1939) “Interactions between the Multiplier Analysis and the Principle of Acceleration,” Review of Economic Statistics 21: 75–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • - (1961) Economics, An Introductory Analysis, 5th ed., McGraw-Hill, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt-Nielsen, K. (1984) Scaling: Why Is Animal Size So Important? Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schrödinger, E. (1944) What Is Life, The Physical Aspect of the Living Cell, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1934) The Theory of Economic Development, Harvard University Press, Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shileifer, A. and D. Treisman (2005) “A Normal Country: Russia after Communism,” Journal of Economic Perspective 19. 1: 151–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stack, H. M. (1997) “The ‘Colonization’ of East Germany?: A Comparative Analysis of German Privatization,” Duke Law Journal 46. 5: 1211–1253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1951) “The Division of Labor Is Limited by the Extent of the Market,” Journal of Political Economy 59: 185–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (1976) “The Efficient Wage Hypothesis, Surplus Labor, and the Distribution of Income in L.D.C.s,” Oxford Economic Papers 28. 2: 185–207.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tikhomirov, V. (2000) The Political Economy of Post-Soviet Russia, St. Martin, New York.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Uhlenbeck, G. E., and L. S. Ornstein (1930) “On the Theory of Brownian Motion,” Physical Review 36. 3: 823–841.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Hagen, J. and R. R. Stauch (2001) “East Germany: Transition with Unification, Experiments, and Experiences,” in M. I. Blejer and M. Skreb (eds) Transition, the First Decade, MIT Press, MA: Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wallis, J. J. and D. C. North (1986) “Measuring the Transaction Sector in the American Economy, 1870–1970,” pp. 95–148, and “Comments” by Lance E. Davis, pp.149–161, in Engerman, Stanley L. and Robert E. Gallman (eds) Long-Term Factors in American Economic Growth, Studies on Income and Wealth, vol. 51 (National Bureau of Economic Research), University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp. 95–148.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, J. (1990) “What Washington Means by Policy Reform?” in J. Williamson (ed) Latin America Adjustment: How Much Has Happened? Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C..

    Google Scholar 

  • Zeng, W. and P. Chen (2008) “Volatility Smile, Relative Deviation, and Trading Strategy—A General Diffusion Model of Stock Pricing Based on Nonlinear Birth-Death Process (in Chinese),” China Economic Qurterly 7.4 (to appear)

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ping Chen.

Additional information

This paper is based on the paper “Equilibrium Illusion and Evolutionary Foundation in Economic Theory” presented at the JAFEE (Japanese Association for Evolutionary Economics) annual meeting in Kagoshima on Sept. 23, 2007. The author is grateful for the inspirational discussions in the past with Paul Samuelson, Richard Day, James Galbraith, Finn Kydland, Edward Prescott, Steven Cheung, Gregory Chow, Ulrich Witt, Joseph Stiglitz, Kurt Dopfer, Yagi Kiichiro, Yuji Aruka, and the recent participants of the Kagoshima meeting.

This work was supported by Grant No. 07BJL004 from the National Social Science Foundation of China.

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chen, P. Equilibrium Illusion, Economic Complexity and Evolutionary Foundation in Economic Analysis. Evolut Inst Econ Rev 5, 81–127 (2008). https://doi.org/10.14441/eier.5.81

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.14441/eier.5.81

Keywords

JEL

Navigation