Skip to main content
Log in

Can Self-interest Explain Cooperation?

  • Article
  • Published:
Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Economists and biologists generally explain cooperation as the result of self-interested action either in repeated interactions or among relatives. We review these models, showing that while repeated interactions in dyads or among relatives do not require other-regarding preferences, cooperation among large numbers of unrelated individuals—a characteristic of human cooperation—cannot be explained in this manner. Other-regarding preferences such as altruism and reciprocity are essential to understanding why humans are, uniquely among animals, a cooperative species.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Alexander, R. D. (1987) The Biology of Moral Systems, Aldine, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1971) “Political and Economic Evaluation of Social Effects and Externalities,” in M. D. Intriligator (ed) Frontiers of Quantitative Economics, Amsterdam, North Holland, pp. 3–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R. and W. D. Hamilton (1981) “The Evolution of Cooperation,” Science 211: 1390–1396.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bliege Bird, R. L., E. A. Smith and D. W. Bird (2001) “The Hunting Handicap: Costly Signaling in Human Foraging Strategies,” Behavioral Ecology and Sociobiology 50: 9–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boone, J. L. (1998) “The Evolution of Magnanimity: When is it Better to Give than to Receive?,” Human Nature 9: 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S. and D. Posel (2005) “Genetic Relatedness Predicts South African Migrant Workers’ Remittances to their Families,” Nature 434: 380–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • - and H. Gintis (2006) A Cooperative Species: Human Sociality and its Evolution (in press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, R. and P. J. Richerson (1988) “The Evolution of Reciprocity in Sizable Groups,” Journal of Theoretical Biology 132: 337–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. (2003) Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.

    Google Scholar 

  • Case, A., I-F. Lin and S. McLanahan (2000) “How Hungry is the Selfish Gene,” Economic Journal 110: 781–804.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clements, K. C. and D. W. Stephens (1995) “Testing Models of Non-kin Cooperation: Mutualism and the Prisoner’s Dilemma,” Animal Behaviour 50: 527–535.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daly, M. and M. Wilson (1988) Homicide, Aldine de Gruyter, NewYork.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dawkins, R. (1989) The Selfish Gene, 2nd ed., Oxford University Press, Oxford.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dugatkin, L. A. and M. Mesterton-Gibbons (1996) “Cooperation Among Unrelated Individuals: Reciprocal Altruism, Byproduct Mutualism, and Group Selection in Fishes,” Biosystems 37: 19–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durrett, R. and L. Simon (1994) “The Importance of Being Discrete (and Spatial),” Theoretical Population Biology 46: 363–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engelmann, D. and U. Fischbacher (2004) “Indirect Reciprocity and Strategic Reputation Building in an Experimental Helping Game,” Department of Economics, University of London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fong, C. M., S. Bowles and H. Gintis (2005) “Reciprocity and the Welfare State,” in H. Gintis, S. Bowles, R. Boyd and E. Fehr (eds) Moral Sentiments and Material Interests: On the Foundations of Cooperation in Economic Life, The MIT Press, Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg, D. and E. Maskin (1986) “The Folk Theorem in Repeated Games with Discounting or with Incomplete Information,” Econometrica 54.3: 533–554.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gachter, S., M. Konigstein and E. Kessler (2004) “Performance Incentives and the Dynamics of Voluntary Cooperation,” University of St. Gallen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghemawat, P. (1995) “Competitive Advantage and Internal Organization: Nucor Revisited,” Journal of Economic and Management Strategy 3.4: 685–717.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghiselin, M. T. (1974) The Economy of Nature and the Evolution of Sex, University of California Press, Berkeley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gintis, H. (2005) “Behavioral Game Theory and Contemporary Economic Theory,” Analyze & Kritik (forthcoming).

    Google Scholar 

  • -, E. A. Smith and S. Bowles (2001) “Costly Signaling and Cooperation,” Journal of Theoretical Biology 213: 103–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • -, S. Bowles, R. Boyd and E. Fehr (2005) Moral Sentiments and Material Interests: On the Foundations of Cooperation in Economic Life, The MIT Press, Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gurven, M., K. Hill and H. Kaplan (2002) “From forest to reservation: Transitions in Food Shearing among the Ache of Paraguay,” Journal of Anthropological Research 58: 93–120.

    Google Scholar 

  • —, A. Magdalena Hurtado and R. Lyles (2000) “Food Transfers among Hiwi Foragers of Venezuela,” Human Ecology 28: 171–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • -, W. Allen-Arave, K. Hill and A. Magdalena Hurtado (2000) “‘It’s a Wonderful Life’: Signaling Generosity AmongtheAche of Paraguay,” Evolution and Human Behavior 21: 263–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, W. D. (1964) “The Genetical Evolution of Social Behavior I & II,” Journal of Theoretical Biology 7: 1–16, 17–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hammerstein, P. (2003) “Why Is Reciprocity So Rare in Social Animals?,” in P. Hammerstein (ed) Genetic and Cultural Evolution of Cooperation, The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, pp. 83–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, D. G. (1997) “Individual Responses to a Group Incentive,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 51.1: 37–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hawkes, K., J. F. O’Connell and N. G. Blurton Jones (2001) “Hadza Meat Sharing,” Evolution and Human Behavior 22: 113–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henrich, J., R. Boyd, S. Bowles, C. Camerer, E. Fehr and H. Gintis (2004) Foundations of Human Sociality: Economic Experiments and Ethnographic Evidence from Fifteen Smallscale Societies, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Joshi, N. V. (1987) “Evolution of Cooperation by Reciprocation Within Structured Demes,” Journal of Genetics 66.1: 69–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan, H. and K. Hill (1985) “Hunting Ability and Reproductive Success among Male Ache Foragers: Preliminary Results,” Current Anthropology 26.1: 131–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knez, M. and D. Simester (2001) “Firm-Wide Incentives and Mutual Monitoring at Continental Airlines,” Journal of Labor Economics 19.4: 743–772.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leimar, O. and P. Hammerstein (2001) “Evolution of Cooperation through Indirect Reciprocity,” Proceedings of the Royal Sciety of London B 268: 745–753.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mandeville, B. (1705) The Fable of the Bees: Private Vices, Publick Benefits.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGranahan, L. M. (2000) “Charity and the Bequest Motive: Evidence from Seventeenth-Century Wills,” Journal of Political Economy 108.6: 1270–1291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milinski, M. (1996) “Byproduct Mutualism, Tit-for-tat Reciprocity and Cooperative Predator Inspection,” Animal Behavior 51: 458–461.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • -, D. Semmann and H.-J. Krambek (2002) “Reputation Helps Solve the “Tragedy of the Commons’,” Nature 415: 224–226.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nowak, M. A. and K. Sigmund (1998) “Evolution of Indirect Reciprocity by Image Scoring,” Nature 393: 573–577.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panchanathan, K. and R. Boyd (2003) “A Tale of Two Defectors: The Importance of Standing for Evolution of Indirect Reciprocity,” Journal of Theoretical Biology 224: 115–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1937 [1776]) The Wealth of Nations, Modern Library, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, E. A. and R. L. Bliege Bird (2000) “Turtle Hunting and Tombstone Opening: Public Generosity as Costly Signaling,” Evolution and Human Behavior 21.4: 245–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • -, R. L. Bird, and D. W. Bird (2002) “Risk and Reciprocity in Meriam Foodsharing,” Evolution and Human Behavior 23: 297–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sosis, R. (2000) “Costly Signaling and Torch Fishing on Ifaluk Atoll,” Evolution and Human Behavior 21.4: 223–244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spence, A. M. (1973) “Job Market Signaling,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 90: 225–243.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stephens, W., C. M. McLinn and J. R. Stevens (2002) “Discounting and Reciprocity in an Iterated Prisoner’s Dilemma,” Science 298: 2216–2218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sugden, R. (1986) The Economics of Rights, Co-operation and Welfare, Basil Blackwell, Oxford.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, M. (1976) Anarchy and Cooperation, John Wiley and Sons, London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trivers, R. L. (1971) “The Evolution of Reciprocal Altruism,” Quarterly Review of Biology 46: 35–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zahavi, A. (1977) “Reliability in Communication Systems and the Evolution of Altruism,” in B. Stonehouse and C. M. Perrins (eds) Evolutionary Ecology, Macmillan Press, London, pp. 253–259.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Samuel Bowles.

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bowles, S., Gintis, H. Can Self-interest Explain Cooperation?. Evolut Inst Econ Rev 2, 21–41 (2005). https://doi.org/10.14441/eier.2.21

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.14441/eier.2.21

Keywords

Navigation