Skip to main content
Log in

Some Comments on the Methodological Principles of Nelson and Winter’s Evolutionary Theory

  • Article
  • Published:
Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Two main sorts of arguments have been employed by Nelson and Winter to justify the existence of an evolutionary research program. The first corresponds to their wish to propose theories at least as robust as neoclassical ones on the same questions. We highlight that Nelson and Winter tried to avoid incommensurability between neoclassical theories and their own theory. They wanted to prevent neoclassical theories to define their evolutionary analysis as an empirical work complementary to the neoclassical theoretical work. We also underscore that the emphasis put on robustness was motivated by the wish to propose an alternative to neoclassical theories. This element was associated with a second wish which was to propose a representation of technical change that would be better than neoclassical theories. By taking the assumptions and outcomes of non-neoclassical theories into account, Nelson and Winter asserted their dissatisfaction with the neoclassical definition of technical change. For these reasons, we argue that Nelson and Winter’s book was a tentative attempt to propose an evolutionary theory as robust as the neoclassical one but based on a better representation of technical change.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Aghion, P. and P. Howitt (1998) Endogenous Growth Theory, MIT Press, Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andersen, E. (1994) Evolutionary Economics: Post-Schumpeterian Contributions, Pinter, London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1962) “Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention,” in R. Nelson (ed) The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity, National Bureau of Economic Research, New York, pp. 609–625.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G. (1982) “Technological Paradigms and Technological Trajectories,” Research Policy 11. 3: 147–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, C. (1974) The Economics of Industrial Innovation, Penguin, Harmondsworth.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, C., J. Clark. and L. Soete (1982) Unemployment and Technical Innovation: a Study of Long Waves and Economic Development, Pinter, London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1953) “The Methodology of Positive Economics,” in M. Friedman (ed) Essays in Positive Economics, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp. 3–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galbraith, J. (1952) American Capitalism: the Concept of Countervailing Power, Houghton Mifflin, Boston.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hahn, F. and R. Solow (1995) A Critical Essay on Macroeconomic Theory, Blackwell Publishers, Oxford.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson, G. (1994) “Institutionalism, ‘Old’ and ‘New’,” in G. Hodgson, W. Samuels and M. Tool (eds) The Elgar Companion to Institutional and Evolutionary Economics A-K, Edward Elgar, Aldershot.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kay, N. (1988) “The R&D Function: Corporate Strategy and Structure,” in G. Dosi, C. Freeman, R. Nelson, G. Silverberg and L. Soete (eds) Technical Change and Economic Theory, Pinter, London, pp. 282–294.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klamer, A. (1983) Conversations with Economists, Rawman and Allanheld, Totowa.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kline, S. J. and N. Rosenberg (1986) “An Overview of Innovation,” in R. Landau and N. Rosenberg (eds), The Positive Sum Strategy. Harnessing Technology for Economic Growth, National Academic Press, Washington, pp. 275–305.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lakatos, I. (1970) “Falsification and the Methodology of Scientific Research Programs,” in I. Lakatos and A. Musgrave (eds) Criticism and the Growth of Knowledge, Cambridge University Press, New York, pp. 91–196.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Malinvaud, E. (1993) “Regard d’un ancien sur les nouvelles théories de la croissance,” Revue Economique 44. 2: 171–188.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. (1959) “The Simple Economics of Basic Scientific Research,” Journal of Political Economy 67. 3: 297–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. (1981) “Research on Productivity Growth and Productivity Differentials: Dead Ends and New Departures,” Journal of Economic Literature 19. 3: 1029–1062.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. (1994) “What Has Been the Matter with the Neoclassical Growth Theory,” in G. Silverberg and L. Soete (eds) The Economics of Growth and Technical Change, Edward Elgar, Aldershot, pp. 290-324.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. (1995) “Recent Evolutionary Theorizing about Economic Change,” Journal of Economic Literature 33. 1: 48–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. (1998) “The Agenda for Growth Theory,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 22: 497–520.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. and S. Winter (1974) “Neoclassical vs Evolutionary Theories of Economic Growth,” Economic Journal 84. 336: 886–905.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. and S. Winter (1977) “In Search of Useful Theory of Innovation,” Research Policy 6. 1: 36–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. and S. Winter (1982) An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Harvard University Press, Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J. (1972) “The Second Crisis of the Economic Theory,” American Economic Review, Papers & Proceedings 62. 2: 1–10.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. (1994) “The Origins of Endogenous Growth,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 8. 1: 3–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, N. (1976) Perspectives on Technology, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. (1942) Capitalism. Socialism and Democracy, Allen and Unwin, London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Silverberg, G. and B. Verspagen (1995) “Evolutionary Theorizing on Economic Growth,” IIASA Working Paper, no. 95078.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. (1957) “Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function,” Review of Economics and Statistics 39. 3: 312–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. (1988) “Technological Change and the Nature of the Firm,” in G. Dosi, C. Freeman, R. Nelson, G. Silverberg and L. Soete (eds) Technical Change and Economic Theory, Pinter, London, pp. 256–281.

    Google Scholar 

  • Winter, S. (1964) “Economic Natural Selection and the Theory of the Firm,” Yale Economic Essays 4: 225–272.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Patrick Eparvier.

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Eparvier, P. Some Comments on the Methodological Principles of Nelson and Winter’s Evolutionary Theory. Evolut Inst Econ Rev 1, 221–234 (2005). https://doi.org/10.14441/eier.1.221

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.14441/eier.1.221

Keywords

JEL

Navigation