1 Introduction

In developing countries, the opportunity cost of children’s time is likely to be higher when the parents’ income-generating capacity is lower, so negative household income shocks will reduce children’s education and play time and increase their work time (Basu and Van 1998). Evidence for such an effect has been found in studies of agricultural productivity shocks (Beegle et al. 2006; Colmer 2013; Guarcello et al. 2008) and employment shocks (Duryea et al. 2007; Guarcello et al. 2010).Footnote 1 Fallon and Tzannatos (1998) and Udry (2006) argue that child labour is a consequence of chronic poverty, and there is some evidence for such a link from cross-country studies (Edmonds and Pavcnik 2005), country-specific studies (Jensen and Nielsen 1997; Edmonds 2005), and cash-transfer experiments (Edmonds 2006; Edmonds and Schady 2009; Bourguignon et al. 2003).

This paper focuses on the effects on children’s time allocation of shocks to parental health. Parental health shocks could have an especially large effect on children’s time, because a child is required not only to provide a substitute for adult labour but also to care for the parent. The child’s education could be adversely affected because the household can no longer afford to pay for it, or because the child has no time to study (Haile and Haile 2012; Rosati and Rossi 2001; Rosenzweig and Evenson 1977; Udry 2006), or because the child is fatigued by strenuous or hazardous employment (Duryea et al. 2007; Heady 2003). There is already a small literature on the links between parental illness, child labour and education, but only two papers (Dillon 2012; Alam 2015) which estimate the impact of adult health shocks on the allocation of children’s time across a range of activities, rather than just on time spent in school.

Our analysis embodies a number of distinctive features. Firstly, we distinguish between different types of child work using two alternative types of disaggregation. We distinguish between different kinds of activity (education, play, domestic chores inside the home and work outside the home), and we also distinguish between (i) time spent on innocuous household chores or light work outside the home and (ii) child labour as defined by organisations such as the International Labour Organisation (ILO) and the United Nations Children’s Emergency Fund (UNICEF). Depending on their age and the type of task they perform, children might benefit from light work: they might acquire skills useful in future life or earn income that can help to finance their own education and health (Cigno and Rosati 2002; Moehling 2005). We believe that this distinction enhances the relevance of our results to policymakers, who may be concerned primarily with child labour as defined by the ILO and UNICEF—i.e. work that is harmful to the child’s wellbeing and personal development. Secondly, we estimate the effects of parental illness using a panel dataset that allows us to control for unobserved heterogeneity at the household level. Such heterogeneity could arise if, for example, there are some parents who put relatively little value on human capital and so invest in neither their own health nor their children’s education. Thirdly, while we do control for shocks to the health of adults in the household other than the mother and father, our main focus is on parental health shocks, and on asymmetries in (i) the effect of maternal health shocks on girls and boys and (ii) the effect of paternal health shocks on girls and boys.

Our study uses data for two cohorts of children in the Ethiopian Young Lives survey. One of the key original contributions of this paper is that we estimate the impact of parental health shocks on the allocation on children’s time in a way that allows for a distinction between child work and child labour. This distinction is based on the definition of child labour developed by UNICEF (United Nations 1989), which is consistent with the guidelines in the ILO’s Minimum Age Convention (ILO 1973) and the resolutions of the 18th International Conference of Labour Statisticians (ILO 2008). This definition takes into account work intensity and the child’s age. We also distinguish between the effects of paternal and maternal illness, and between the effects on sons and the effects on daughters. Our results are based on fixed-effects estimates that allow for unobserved heterogeneity.

We find that parental illness has a large and statistically significant effect on the allocation of children’s time, but that there are asymmetries between maternal and paternal illness. Paternal illness reduces time spent in school while increasing time spent in income-generating work, but maternal illness reduces time spent in play and income-generating work while increasing time spent in domestic work. Moreover, maternal illness has a larger impact on daughters while paternal illness has a larger impact on sons. In this way, the effects of parental illness appear to reflect traditional gender roles within the household. There is also some heterogeneity in the effects of parental illness on the prevalence of child labour. Overall, serious maternal illness is associated with a ten percentage point increase in prevalence while serious paternal illness has a smaller effect. However, maternal illness has a relatively large effect on prevalence among girls and paternal illness a relatively large effect on prevalence among boys.

2 Data and descriptive statistics

Our data are taken from the Ethiopian Young Lives surveys of 2006 and 2009 (www.younglives.org.uk/content/ethiopia).Footnote 2 As with Young Lives surveys in other countries, the Ethiopian sample comprises two cohorts of children in a stratified sample of villages: one cohort was aged 0.5–1.5 years in 2002 while the other was aged 7.5–8.5 years in 2002. It is the existence of two cohorts that provides much of the variation in the child age variable in our sample. Before attrition, the younger cohort comprises 2000 children and the older cohort 1000 children.Footnote 3 After attrition due to mortality and other factors,Footnote 4 and after excluding children aged under five or living in single-parent households at the time of the survey, we have sample sizes of 1299 and 970 respectively. However, only one child is sampled in each household, so there is no distinction between child fixed effects and household fixed effects.

Table 1 shows summary statistics for children’s daily time allocation between play, schooling (including homework), domestic chores and income-generating work, and Figs. 1, 2, 3 and 4 contain the corresponding histograms. Income-generating work includes activities such as street vending, work on the farm or serving in the family store. Domestic chores include activities such as washing, cooking, cleaning and caregiving; these definitions are consistent with those of the United Nations (2009). The table shows a marked upward trend in schooling time and downward trend in play time; this corresponds to an increase in the school enrolment rate from 56% in 2006 to 85% in 2009.Footnote 5 There is also a substantial percentage increase in income-generating work time. On average, income-generating work only makes up a small proportion of children’s time, but the low mean is accompanied by a high standard deviation, so there are some children who are spending a substantial proportion of their time in income-generating work. Note that this work is not motivated by a need to pay for schooling, because Ethiopian public schools do not charge fees. The table also shows some gender asymmetries. Although boys and girls spend roughly the same amount of time on average in play, schooling and work, the girls’ work time is much more dominated by domestic chores while boys spend a substantial amount of time in income-generating work. This may reflect cultural norms relating to gender roles: for example, boys do not normally cook, and it is sometimes unacceptable for a girl to leave home unaccompanied. The figures show that the distributions of all four activities are left-skewed, but the skewness is more marked for schooling and income-generating work, with many children either not attending school or not going out to work. Finally, the table includes mean values for each activity disaggregated by the health status of the parents. It can be seen that parental illness is generally associated with an increase time spent in domestic chores and income-generating work and a decrease in time spent in play and schooling. Note, however, that these are unconditional associations which do not necessarily correspond to a causal effect.

Table 1 Descriptive statistics
Fig. 1
figure 1

Histogram of play hours (2006 and 2009 surveys combined)

Fig. 2
figure 2

Histogram of schooling hours (2006 and 2009 surveys combined)

Fig. 3
figure 3

Histogram of domestic chore hours (2006 and 2009 surveys combined)

Fig. 4
figure 4

Histogram of income-generating work hours (2006 and 2009 surveys combined)

Neither of the work categories in Table 1 corresponds to standard definitions of child labour. In this paper, we will analyse both the work categories in Table 1 and child labour as defined by UNICEF. For children aged 5–11 years, child labour is defined as domestic chores in excess of 28 h per week or any income-generating work; for children aged 12–14 years, child labour is defined as domestic chores in excess of 28 h per week or income-generating work is excess of 14 h per week (there are no children in our sample over the age of 14). Using these definitions, the incidence of child labour across the two rounds of the survey is 54% for both age groups. The under-11s account for two thirds of the sample and therefore two thirds of the cases of child labour.

Table 1 also reports the proportion of children whose mothers or fathers report having been ill in the 3 years prior to the survey.Footnote 6 The incidence of maternal illness is higher than the incidence of paternal illness; moreover, the incidence of paternal illness is the same across the two surveys while the incidence of maternal incidence has risen. These asymmetries will matter if the effects of parental illness are gender-specific. In estimating the effects of parental illness, we will need to control for other negative shocks to the household that might affect child labour: illness among other members of the household, the death of livestock, crop failure, theft, the loss of paid employment and forced eviction. Three-year incidence rates for these shocks are also reported in Table 1. Other control variables in our model include measures of the age and highest school grade previously attained by the child, the child’s mother and the child’s father; whether the child has a step-mother or step-father; the household’s size, wealth level and access to risk-sharing institutions; the sex of the household head and a household power index for the mother; the local community’s level of access to healthcare and microfinance services; the incidence of community-level droughts and floods, and whether the community is rural or urban. Definitions and summary statistics for these variables appear in the Appendix; note that the questions in the Young Lives survey relate to serious illnesses only: the results that follow should be interpreted as estimates of the effect of a serious parental illness within the past 3 years on the current allocation of the child’s time.Footnote 7

3 Modelling the determinants of child work and child labour

3.1 Modelling child work

We first estimate the effect of parental illness on the number of hours of a child’s time that are allocated to the different activities in Table 2. Our estimates are based on a fixed-effects Poisson model with errors clustered at the community level.Footnote 8 For each activity j, the dependent variable (y ijt ) is the amount of time that child i records spending on that activity in survey round t. This variable is assumed to have a Poisson distribution with a mean equal to:

Table 2 Determinants of on time spent in different activities
$$ \mathrm{E}\left({y}_{ij t}\right)=\exp \left({\gamma}_{1j}{h}_{it}^m+{\gamma}_{2j}{h}_{it}^f+{x}_{it}^{\prime }{\beta}_j+{\eta}_{ij}\right) $$
(1)

Here, \( {h}_{it}^m \) and \( {h}_{it}^f \) are indicator variables for the incidence of paternal and maternal illness in the previous 3 years, x it is a vector comprising the control variables listed above, and η ij is a child-specific fixed effect; the β and γ terms are parameters to be estimated. The model is fitted to the full sample of 2269 children, except in the case of schooling, where we exclude children initially aged 5–6 years because the first year of primary education is for children aged 7–8 years.Footnote 9

Before discussing the estimates of the parameters in Eq. (1), we should comment on the assumption that \( {h}_{it}^m \) and \( {h}_{it}^f \) are exogenous to y ijt . There are several different potential sources of endogeneity. Firstly, there could be some household-level characteristics that are associated both with an unhealthy adult lifestyle and with decisions about the allocation of children’s time. Secondly, there could be household-level characteristics that are associated both with decisions about fertility (which could influence parental health) and the allocation of children’s time. Thirdly, the amount of work a child is doing for her parents could affect their subsequent health. In relation to the first two points, we note that the vector x it includes a wide range of child- and household-level characteristics, which are listed in the Appendix. For unobserved heterogeneity to affect the consistency of our estimates of the γ parameters, this heterogeneity would have to be uncorrelated with the elements of x it ; we suggest that there is unlikely to be a large amount of such heterogeneity. Moreover, we have fitted a fixed-effects model, so unobserved heterogeneity that is time-invariant will have no effect on our estimates. In relation to the third point, we acknowledge that the ideal approach would be to fit an instrumental variable (IV) model, but there is no obvious IV for parental health in the dataset. Instead, we explore the possibility of reverse causality by fitting a model of \( {h}_{i2009}^m \) and \( {h}_{2009}^f \) conditional on yij2006. Such a model appears in the Appendix: it shows that child time allocation in 2006 has no significant effect on parental health in 2009, and the point estimates of the effects are very close to zero. This gives us some reason to believe that there will not be a large amount of endogeneity bias in our estimates; nevertheless, the absence of an IV should be noted as a caveat in a causal interpretation of the γ parameters in Eq. (1). A second caveat in the interpretation of our results is that our self-reported parental illness measures do not include any disaggregation by type of illness or by severity of illness, and the γ parameters should be interpreted as mean effects across all types of illness.

Table 2 includes estimates of the γ parameters, which can be interpreted as the percentage change in the number of hours worked, on average, in the case of maternal or paternal illness. The table indicates some asymmetries between the effects of maternal and paternal illness. Maternal illness is associated with a 30% increase in the amount of time spent on domestic chores; correspondingly, there is a 10% reduction in the amount of time spent in play and a 17% reduction in the amount of time spent in income-generating work; all of these effects are significant at the 5% level. The estimated effect of maternal illness on time in school is very small and insignificantly different from zero. Paternal illness is associated with a 28% increase in the amount of time spent in income-generating work; correspondingly, there is a 9% reduction in the amount of time spent in school; both of these effects are significant at the 1% level. The effects on maternal illness on domestic chore time and of paternal illness on income-generating work time are unsurprising, given the traditional gender roles of adults in most Ethiopian households (Haile and Haile 2012).Footnote 10 However, it is more surprising that only paternal illness reduces time in school. One possible explanation is that the extra income-generating work resulting from paternal illness takes up whole days of a child’s time, making it impossible to go to school; the extra domestic chores resulting from maternal illness might more easily be fitted around the school day. Previous studies have also found a relatively small effect of parental mortality and morbidity on school hours. In Tanzania, for example, Ainsworth et al. (2005) find that the mortality of one parent (either the mother or the father) has a small and statistically insignificant effect on the number of school hours, while Alam (2015) finds that maternal illness has no significant effect on the probability of a child attending school. In a study of ten Sub-Saharan African countries, Case et al. (2004) find significant effects of the death of one parent on the probability of school attendance, but the fall in probability is typically only about five percentage points.Footnote 11

Estimates of the β parameters in Eq. (1) appear in the Appendix, along with a discussion of the effects of all of the control variables. Table 2 also includes parameter estimates for two control variables of particular interest. These show that firstly, the effects of illness of a member of the household other than the mother or father are very small and insignificantly different from zero, and secondly, domestic chore time is reduced by 22% when the household lives in a location with a local health centre. This effect is significant at the 1% level, and suggests that extension of access to primary healthcare would be an effective way to mitigate the impact of parental illness on children, as well as reducing the burden of illness on adults.

The Appendix contains further results that focus on the extensive margin of the Table 2 effects, showing the impact of parental illness on the probability that children will be spending any time on domestic chores or income-generating work. It turns out that there are also large effects at the extensive margin: maternal illness raises the probability of involvement in some chores by five percentage points and reduces the probability of involvement in income-generating work by the same amount; paternal illness raises the probability of involvement in income-generating work by four percentage points. Moreover, proximity to a local health centre reduces the probability of involvement in domestic chores by about five percentage points.

It is important to remember that the γ parameters measure percentage changes in the time allocated to a particular activity, not the absolute number of hours. Nevertheless, absolute changes can be computed at specific values of the explanatory variables, for example, at their mean values. Across the two rounds of the survey, the mean number of play hours is 5.1 and the mean number of hours of schooling is 5.5; the corresponding figure for domestic chores is 2.9 and the corresponding figure for income-generating work is 1.3. The Table 2 results imply that at these mean values, maternal illness results in a decrease in play time of 5.1 × 0.098 ≈ 0.5 h per day, a decrease in schooling time of 5.5 × 0.030 ≈ 0.2 h, and a decrease in income-generating work time of 1.3 × 0.170 ≈ 0.2 h; the corresponding increase in chore time is 2.9 × 0.299 ≈ 0.9 h.Footnote 12 The model does not constrain the effects to sum to zero, because the diary does not ask children to account for all 24 h in a day, but the effects do approximately sum to zero at the mean; this is also true of paternal illness.

The results in Table 2 are based on the assumption that the effects of parental illness and of the control variables are linearly separable. There are two main reasons why this assumption might not hold. Firstly, when only one parent is ill, part of the family’s coping strategy might be for the other parent to reduce his or her leisure time, but when both parents are ill, this will not be possible, and the effect on the children will be magnified. We can explore this possibility by adding an interaction term \( {h}_{it}^m\times {h}_{it}^f \) to the right-hand side of Eq. (1). Secondly, the effects of parental illness on the allocation of a child’s time might depend on the characteristics of the child. For example, the effect of illness on the value of the marginal hour allocated to education might depend on the child’s existing level of educational attainment, or the effect of illness on the value of the marginal hour allocated to work might depend on the child’s age. We can explore this possibility by adding interaction terms in \( {h}_{it}^m \) and educational attainment and in \( {h}_{it}^f \) and educational attainment, or in \( {h}_{it}^m \) and age and in \( {h}_{it}^f \) and age. One challenge in the interpretation of a model with interaction terms is that these terms are necessarily correlated with each other, and the correlations will bias the standard errors upwards. When we fit a model with more than one type of interaction term, almost none of the individual parameters is significantly different from zero. Nevertheless, we can explore the separability assumption by fitting a set of models, each one of which includes a different type of interaction term. The results of such an exercise are reported in Tables 3 and 4.

Table 3 The effects of parental illness: models with an interaction term
Table 4 The effects of parental illness: models with interaction terms in child characteristics

Table 3 shows the results of adding \( {h}_{it}^m\times {h}_{it}^f \) to the model. Here, the interaction term in the play and income-generating work equations is insignificantly different from zero, and the addition of the interaction term makes little difference to the γ parameter estimates. However, the coefficient on the interaction term is significantly less than zero in the schooling equation and significantly greater than zero in the domestic chores equation, indicating that when both parents are ill, the effect on the substitution out of schooling and into chores is magnified. The addition of the interaction term makes the γ parameter estimates in the schooling and chores equations larger in absolute value, but these differences are not statistically significant.

Table 4 shows the results of adding interaction terms in educational attainment (measured as the highest school grade attained) or in age. Here, the one large and significant interaction effect is that the impact of paternal illness on time allocated to income-generating work is smaller for older children or for more educated children. Age and educational attainment are so highly correlated that it makes little sense to include both interaction terms in a single model, but the most plausible interpretation of the effect is that when a child is closer to completing school, the parents are more reluctant to remove the child from school in order to make up for income lost through paternal illness. There is a qualitatively similar result for the effect of paternal illness on time allocated to domestic chores, but here the effect is much smaller and of marginal statistical significance.

Finally, Table 5 shows estimates of the γ parameters when the model (without interaction terms) is fitted to a sample of boys only and a sample of girls only. There are some asymmetries in the effects of parental illness on girls and boys. For boys, the effects of paternal illness are similar to (but somewhat larger than) the aggregate effects in Table 2: when his father is ill, a boy can be expected to spend 29% more time in income-generating work and 14% less time in school. The estimated effects of paternal illness on girls are all much smaller and insignificantly different from zero. By contrast, the effects of maternal illness are larger for girls than for boys: the increase in girls’ domestic chore time is 31% (versus 26% for boys) and the reduction in girls’ play time is 12% (versus 8% for boys). The most marked asymmetry in the effect of maternal illness relates to income-generating work time, which falls by 34% for girls but only 8% for boys: there is thus some evidence that whatever income-generating work girls are doing can be sacrificed if the mother needs more help in the home, but this is not the case for boys.Footnote 13 Note that the effects of parental illness on girls’ time do not depend on whether she has any brothers, and the effects on boys’ time do not depend on whether he has any sisters: when the illness variables are interacted with indicator variables for whether there are no boys in the house (in the case of girls) or no girls in the house (in the case of boys), the coefficients on these interaction terms are insignificantly different from zero (p > 0.1). Recall also that children in single-parent households are excluded from the sample, so the estimated effects of maternal (paternal) illness are for households in which the father (mother) is present.

Table 5 The effects of parental illness on time spent in different activities (sub-samples)

3.2 Modelling child labour

The second part of our empirical analysis involves estimation of the determinants of the prevalence of child labour. The harm to individual children from being subjected to child labour will depend on a number of factors, including both the total number of labour hours and the type of work involved. Measuring the extent of harm is a topic for future research, and here we follow previous studies (Baland and Robinson 2000; Basu and Van 1998; Beegle et al. 2006; Ranjan 1999) in focussing on a binary variable (z it ) which indicates whether child i is subjected to any child labour in survey period t. Assume that the data-generating process for z it takes the form of a fixed-effects Probit model:

$$ \mathrm{P}\left({z}_{it}=1\right)=\Phi \left({\alpha}_1{h}_{it}^m+{\alpha}_2{h}_{it}^f+{x}_{it}^{\prime}\varphi +{\mu}_i\right) $$
(2)

Here Ф(.) is the cumulative normal density function, μ i is a child-specific fixed effect, and the other variables are as in Eq. (1). Although this model cannot be estimated directly, consistent estimates of the α and φ parameters can be obtained by replacing μ i with a linear function of the child-specific mean values of \( {h}_{it}^m \), \( {h}_{it}^f \) and x it plus a random effect ε(i):

$$ \mathrm{P}\left({z}_{it}=1\right)=\Phi \left({\alpha}_1{h}_{it}^m+{\alpha}_2{h}_{it}^f+{x}_{it}^{\hbox{'}}\varphi +{\pi}_1{\overline{h}}_i^m+{\pi}_2{\overline{h}}_i^f+{\overline{x}}_i^{\hbox{'}}\omega +\varepsilon (i)\right),\kern0.75em \varepsilon (i)\sim \kern0.5em \mathrm{N}\left(\delta, \kern0.5em {\sigma}^2\right) $$
(3)

This is the correlated random-effects (CRE) model (Wooldridge 2011). For comparison, we also estimate a simple random-effects Probit model in which the π and ω parameters are set to zero.

Table 6 shows the average partial effects of maternal and paternal illness on the probability of child labour, i.e. Ф ′ (.) ∙ α1 and Ф ′ (.) ∙ α2 evaluated at the mean value of Ф(.), along with the corresponding standard errors. Estimates of the other parameters in the model are available on request. It can be seen that the CRE and simple random-effects estimates are quite similar, although the restrictions implicit in the latter can be rejected at the 1% level using a χ 2 test. Maternal illness has a relatively large effect on the probability of child labour: in the CRE model, this probability is estimated to increase by about ten percentage points when the mother is ill, an effect that is significant at the 1% level. The effect of paternal illness is much smaller and in the CRE model is insignificantly different from zero.

Table 6 Average partial effects of illness on the probability of child labour

The asymmetry in the effects of maternal and paternal illness is somewhat surprising: one might have expected the father’s illness to increase child labour through its effect on household income (Basu and Van 1998; Fallon and Tzannatos 1998; Udry 2006). However, it is consistent with the results regarding child time allocation discussed above. Maternal illness mainly affects time spent on domestic chores while paternal illness mainly affects time spent in income-generating work. The percentage increase in domestic chores following maternal illness is approximately equal to the percentage increase in income-generating work following paternal illness (see Table 2), but the average amount of time spent in domestic chores is much higher than the average amount of time spent in income-generating work (see Table 1). Therefore, maternal illness is associated with larger absolute increases in total child work time, and is more likely to take the child’s work hours over the threshold that defines child labour.

One possible reason for the relatively large absolute effects of maternal illness is that children’s labour is a closer substitute for women’s labour than it is for men’s, either for cultural reasons or because men’s labour often requires upper body strength that children lack, whereas women’s labour involves stamina that children do have. In the Appendix, we explore this idea by looking at the effects of illness on household consumption. We show that paternal illness leads to a significant reduction in household expenditure. This suggests that the average household’s response to paternal illness is a combination of reduced spending and a moderate increase in the children’s income-generating work time: the consumption financed by the marginal hour which a healthy father spends in income-generating work seems not to be essential. However, we also find that maternal illness leads to no significant reduction in household expenditure. The lost maternal labour hours are probably mainly in domestic chores, but the household does not respond by reducing paternal income-generating work time and the consumption it finances: rather, the children must make up for the mother’s lost hours.

Table 7 shows average partial effects from the CRE model fitted to girl-only and boy-only sub-samples. It can be seen that the effect of maternal illness on girls is larger than that on boys. On average, maternal illness raises the probability of child labour for girls by 13 percentage points (an effect significant at the 1% level) and the probability of child labour for boys by only five percentage points (an effect not quite significant at the 5% level). In contrast, paternal illness raises the probability of child labour for boys by seven percentage points (an effect significant at the 5% level) while having no significant impact on girls. Taken together, the results in Tables 5 and 7 suggest that girls’ labour is a very close substitute for women’s labour but no substitute for men’s labour, while boys’ labour is a moderately close substitute for both men’s and women’s labour. This is consistent with evidence that child labour is a closer substitute for women’s labour than it is for men’s (Diamond and Fayed 1998; Ray 2000).

Table 7 Average partial effects of illness on the probability of child labour (sub-samples)

4 Conclusions

Health shocks are among the most unpredictable and costly causes of economic hardship in developing countries. When a family member is ill, households face loss of income and large, out-of-pocket payments for medical care (Sparrow et al. 2014). This paper contributes to the growing body of evidence that many households cope with such shocks by reallocating the time of family members (Gertler and Gruber 2002; Wagstaff 2007). We show that in at least one country—Ethiopia—parental health shocks have a large effect on the allocation of children’s time.Footnote 14

Our results are based on estimates from fixed-effects models applied to longitudinal data from the Ethiopian Young Lives survey. Interpreting our estimates as causal effects (subject to the caveat noted in Section 3.1), we find that paternal illness reduces children’s time spent in school and increases their time spent in income-generating work, while maternal illness reduces time spent in play and increases time spent in domestic work. Maternal illness has a relatively large effect on girls while paternal illness has a relatively large effect on boys, which suggests that the allocation of both adult and child time is influenced by traditional gender roles. Moreover, parental illness has significant effects on the prevalence of child labour, i.e. the proportion of children engaged in work detrimental to their personal development. Here the effects of maternal illness are larger than those of paternal illness, which reflects the fact that maternal illness has a relatively large absolute effect on the number of hours that children work.

These results suggest that existing studies may underestimate the size of the association between household welfare and child labour. Measures of welfare are often based on poverty indices related to household income or wealth, and these measures are more strongly correlated with the income-generating work of men than with the domestic work of women in traditional societies. Negative shocks to the supply of labour for domestic work can nevertheless lead to substantial reductions in household welfare, and Ethiopian households’ coping strategy for such shocks seems to entail effects on children that are at least as large as the effects of lost income-generating capacity through paternal illness. A further implication is that when estimating the return to public investment in adult (and particularly women’s) health, it is important to account for the effect of adult health on children’s time allocation.

How can the effects of parental illness on child labour be mitigated? Firstly, as shown in Table 2, access to local healthcare services can reduce the impact of parental illness on some types of child work, and in some contexts, the extension of microfinance facilities can help household to insure themselves against illness (Gertler et al. 2009). However, some programmes to extend healthcare have had no significant effect on child labour (Rocha and Soares 2010), and it may be that the effects of maternal illness cannot be fully mitigated unless someone else can be found to do the housework. Some households might be able to rely on extended family members or friends to help out when the mother is ill, but others will have to buy in help; this means that development outcomes for many children will depend crucially on the existence of an efficient market for domestic help.