Skip to main content
Log in

Global Financial Cycles and Risk Premiums

  • Research Article
  • Published:
IMF Economic Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies the synchronization of financial cycles across 17 advanced economies over the past 150 years. The comovement in credit, house prices, and equity prices has reached historical highs in the past three decades. While comovement of credit and house prices increased in line with growing real sector integration, comovement of equity prices has increased above and beyond growing real sector integration. The sharp increase in the comovement of global equity markets is particularly notable. We demonstrate that fluctuations in risk premiums, and not risk-free rates and dividends, account for a large part of the observed equity price synchronization after 1990. We also show that US monetary policy has come to play an important role as a source of fluctuations in risk appetite across global equity markets. These fluctuations are transmitted across both fixed and floating exchange rate regimes, but the effects are more muted in floating rate regimes.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Dumas et al. (2003) explain the excessive correlation of equity prices over fundamentals through the excessive volatility of a common stochastic discount factor.

  2. In the subsequent correlation analysis, we detrend all series with the exception of interest rates and equity return premiums, which are stationary in the long run.

  3. All figures and tables in this paper are based on the authors’ own calculations.

  4. While the terminal value influences the level of \(Q^{RN}\) at the end of the sample, the comovement results, which are based on the detrended \(Q^{RN}\), look very similar for a broad range of terminal value assumptions.

  5. For detrending methods that put more weight on year-to-year changes, the discrepancy between actual equity price comovement, and risk-neutral price comovement decreases (see Figs. 17 to 23 in the appendix). This suggests that dividends and risk-free rates are better at explaining equity price comovement in the short term than in the medium term, where discrepancies between the comovement implied by the risk-neutral price measure and actual equity prices can build up.

  6. It is reasonable to expect a certain degree of cross-sectional dependence in an international macroeconomic dataset, because countries are likely to be influenced by common disturbances. Also typical of macroeconomic data, these disturbances are likely to exhibit temporal persistence. In order to account for such cross-sectional and temporal dependencies in our data, we calculate confidence bands based on Driscoll–Kraay standard errors with five autocorrelation lags (Driscoll and Kraay 1998). Driscoll–Kraay standard errors are a nonparametric technique that is robust to very general forms of dependencies across time and space. The technique is well suited to our macroeconomic dataset, because it relies on large-T asymptotics, without placing any restrictions on the limiting behavior of the number of countries.

  7. This is assuming that innovations to center-country rates are not correlated with other shocks. For correlated shocks, the contemporaneous response reflects expectation errors related to different shocks.

  8. The extent of international financial market integration in the late nineteenth and late twentieth centuries differs in several respects. While (net) cross-border capital flows and (net) foreign asset positions are comparable across both globalizations (Obstfeld and Taylor 2004), financial globalization in the late twentieth century encompassed a wider range of financial assets than did its late nineteenth-century precursor (Bordo et al. 1998). In particular, late nineteenth-century financial globalization was focused in industries with high tangible capital that were less plagued by information asymmetries, such as railways, public bonds, mining and public utilities. Put differently, measured risk premiums might not be comparable across time.

  9. For open economy models where international spillovers become stronger in the level of intermediary leverage see Devereux and Yetman (2010) and Ueda (2012).

  10. Note the assumption of the transversality condition \(lim_{k\rightarrow \infty }\rho ^k \delta _{t+k} = 0\), as well as \(E_t \delta _t = \delta _t\).

  11. Note that while the general setup follows Ammer and Mei (1996), the term \({\tilde{e}}_{r,t+1}\) refers to foreign log real interest rates here, instead of domestic log real rates as in Ammer and Mei (1996). This change allows us to investigate the relative importance of monetary policy synchronization in the synchronicity of equity return premiums.

  12. This value is directly gleaned from the data according to \(\rho _i = (1+ exp(\overline{\delta _i}))\), with \(\overline{\delta _i}\) denoting the mean of country i’s log dividend-price ratio. For our annual data the values for \(\rho \) concentrate around 0.96.

  13. All bilateral VARs have been estimated with one lag, which is our preferred lag order given the relatively short time span covered by the subsamples we are interested in.

References

  • Adrian, Tobias, and Hyun Song Shin. 2009. Money, Liquidity, and Monetary Policy. American Economic Review 99 (2): 600–605.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aikman, David, Andrew G. Haldane, and Benjamin D. Nelson. 2014. Curbing the Credit Cycle. Economic Journal 125 (585): 1072–1109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof, George A., and Robert J. Shiller. 2010. Animal Spirits: How Human Psychology Drives the Economy, and Why It Matters for Global Capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alpanda, Sami, and Uluc Aysun. 2014. International Transmission of Financial Shocks in An Estimated DSGE Model. Journal of International Money and Finance 47: 21–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ammer, John, and Jianping Mei. 1996. Measuring International Economic Linkages with Stock Market Data. Journal of Finance 51 (5): 1743–1763.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bacchetta, Philippe, and Eric van Wincoop. 2013. Sudden Spikes in Global Risk. Journal of International Economics 89 (2): 511–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Backus, David K., Patrick J. Kehoe, and Finn E. Kydland. 1992. International Real Business Cycles. Journal of Political Economy 100 (4): 745–775.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bekaert, Geert, Marie Hoerova, and Marco Lo Duca. 2013. Risk, Uncertainty and Monetary Policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (7): 771–788.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, Ben S., and Kenneth N. Kuttner. 2005. What Explains the Stock Market’s Reaction to Federal Reserve Policy? Journal of Finance 60 (3): 1221–1257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjørnland, Hilde C., and Kai Leitemo. 2009. Identifying the Interdependence Between US Monetary Policy and the Stock Market. Journal of Monetary Economics 56 (2): 275–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bordalo, Pedro, Nicola Gennaioli, and Andrei Shleifer. 2012. Salience Theory of Choice Under Risk. Quarterly Journal of Economics 127 (3): 1243–1285.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bordo, Michael D., Barry Eichengreen, and Jongwoo Kim. 1998. Was There Really an Earlier Period of International Financial Integration Comparable to Today? NBER Working Paper 6738.

  • Bordo, Michael D., and Thomas Helbling. 2003. Have National Business Cycles Become More Synchronized? NBER Working Paper 10130.

  • Bruno, Valentina, and Hyun Song Shin. 2014. Cross-Border Banking and Global Liquidity. Review of Economic Studies 82 (2): 535–564.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruno, Valentina, and Hyun Song Shin. 2015. Capital Flows and the Risk-Taking Channel of Monetary Policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 71: 119–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cagliarini, Adam, and Fiona Price. 2017. Exploring the Link Between the Macroeconmic and Financial Cycles. RBA Working Paper.

  • Campbell, John Y. 1991. A Variance Decomposition for Stock Returns. Economic Journal 101 (405): 157–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, John Y., and Robert J. Shiller. 1988. The Dividend-Price Ratio and Expectations of Future Dividends and Discount Factors. Review of Financial Studies 1 (3): 195–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canova, Fabio. 2005. The Transmission of US Shocks to Latin America. Journal of Applied Econometrics 20 (2): 229–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cassis, Youssef, Richard S. Grossman, and Catherine R. Schenk. 2016. The Oxford Handbook of Banking and Financial History. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Castelnuovo, Efrem, and Salvatore Nisticò. 2010. Stock Market Conditions and Monetary Policy in a DSGE Model for the US. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34 (9): 1700–1731.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cerutti, Eugenio, Stijn Claessens, and Lev Ratnovski. 2014. Global Liquidity and Drivers of Cross-Border Bank Flows. IMF Working Paper 14/69.

  • Cetorelli, Nicola, and Linda S. Goldberg. 2012. Banking Globalization and Monetary Transmission. Journal of Finance 67 (5): 1811–1843.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chadha, Jagjit S., Lucio Sarno, and Giorgio Valente. 2004. Monetary Policy Rules, Asset Prices, and Exchange Rates. IMF Economic Review 51 (3): 529–552.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiţu, Livia, Barry Eichengreen, and Arnaud Mehl. 2014. When Did the Dollar Overtake Sterling as the Leading International Currency? Evidence from the Bond Markets. Journal of Development Economics 111: 225–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Claessens, Stijn, M. Ayhan Kose, and Marco E. Terrones. 2011. Financial Cycles: What? How? When? NBER International Seminar on Macroeconomics 7 (1): 303–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane, John H. 2005. Asset Pricing, Revised ed. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dedola, Luca, and Giovanni Lombardo. 2012. Financial Frictions, Financial Integration and the International Propagation of Shocks. Economic Policy 27 (70): 319–359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Devereux, Michael B., and James Yetman. 2010. Leverage Constraints and the International Transmission of Shocks. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 42 (s1): 71–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drehmann, Mathias, Claudio Borio, and Kostas Tsatsaronis. 2012. Characterising the Financial Cycle: Don’t Lose Sight of the Medium Term! BIS Working Papers 380.

  • Driscoll, John C., and Aart C. Kraay. 1998. Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimation with Spatially Dependent Panel Data. Review of Economics and Statistics 80 (4): 549–560.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dumas, Bernard, Campbell R. Harvey, and Pierre Ruiz. 2003. Are Correlations of Stock Returns Justified by Subsequent Changes in National Outputs? Journal of International Money and Finance 22 (6): 777–811.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ehrmann, Michael, Marcel Fratzscher, and Roberto Rigobon. 2011. Stocks, Bonds, Money Markets and Exchange Rates: Measuring International Financial Transmission. Journal of Applied Econometrics 26 (6): 948–974.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engsted, Tom, and Carsten Tanggaard. 2004. The Comovement of US and UK Stock Markets. European Financial Management 10 (4): 593–607.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feis, Herbert. 1964. Europe, the World’s Banker, 1870–1914: An Account of European Foreign Investment and the Connection of World Finance with Diplomacy Before the War. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Forbes, Kristin J., and Roberto Rigobon. 2002. No Contagion, Only Interdependence: Measuring Stock Market Comovements. The Journal of Finance 57 (5): 2223–2261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fostel, Ana, and John Geanakoplos. 2008. Leverage Cycles and the Anxious Economy. The American Economic Review 98 (4): 1211–1244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furlanetto, Francesco. 2011. Does Monetary Policy React to Asset Prices? Some International Evidence. International Journal of Central Banking 7 (3): 91–111.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galí, Jordi, and Luca Gambetti. 2015. The Effects of Monetary Policy on Stock Market Bubbles: Some Evidence. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 7 (1): 233–257.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gennaioli, Nicola, and Andrei Shleifer. 2010. What Comes to Mind. Quarterly Journal of Economics 125 (4): 1399–1433.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gertler, Mark, and Peter Karadi. 2015. Monetary Policy Surprises, Credit Costs, and Economic Activity. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 7 (1): 44–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gürkaynak, Refet S., Brian Sack, and Eric T. Swanson. 2005. Do Actions Speak Louder than Words? The Response of Asset Prices to Monetary Policy Actions and Statements. International Journal of Central Banking 1 (1): 55–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, James D. 2018. Why You Should Never Use the Hodrick-Prescott Filter. Review of Economics and Statistics 100 (5): 831–843.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harding, Don, and Adrian Pagan. 2002. Dissecting the Cycle: A Methodological Investigation. Journal of Monetary Economics 49 (2): 365–381.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hume, David. 1742. Of the Balance of Trade. In Essays: Moral, Political, and Literary, 1987th ed, ed. Eugene F Miller. Indianapolis: V. Liberty Fund Inc. chapter II.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ilzetzki, Ethan, Carmen M. Reinhart, and Kenneth S. Rogoff. 2017. Exchange Rate Arrangements Entering the 21st century: Which Anchor will Hold? NBER Working Paper 23134.

  • Jordà, Òscar. 2005. Estimation and Inference of Impulse Responses by Local Projections. American Economic Review 95 (1): 161–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jordà, Òscar, Katharina Knoll, Dmitry Kuvshinov, Moritz Schularick, and Alan M. Taylor. 2017a. The Rate of Return on Everything, 1870-2015. NBER Working Paper 24112. Forthcoming in Quarterly Journal of Economics

  • Jordà, Òscar, Moritz Schularick, and Alan M. Taylor. 2015. Betting the House. Journal of International Economics 96: 2–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jordà, Òscar, Moritz Schularick, and Alan M. Taylor. 2016. Macrofinancial History and the New Business Cycle Facts. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 31 (1): 213–263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jordà, Òscar, Moritz Schularick, and Alan M. Taylor. 2017. The Effects of Quasi-Random Monetary Experiments. NBER Working Paper 23074.

  • Kahneman, Daniel, and Amos Tversky. 1979. Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk. Econometrica 47 (2): 263–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kapetanios, George. 2008. A Bootstrap Procedure for Panel Data Sets with Many Cross-sectional Units. Econometrics Journal 11 (2): 377–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim, Soyoung. 2001. International Transmission of US Monetary Policy Shocks: Evidence from VAR’s. Journal of Monetary Economics 48 (2): 339–372.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kindleberger, Charles P. 1978. Manias, Panics, and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises. New York: Wiley.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, Michael W., and Jay C. Shambaugh. 2008. The Dynamics of Exchange Rate Regimes: Fixes, Floats, and Flips. Journal of International Economics 75 (1): 70–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, Michael W., and Jay C. Shambaugh. 2015. Rounding the Corners of the Policy Trilemma: Sources of Monetary Policy Autonomy. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 7 (4): 33–66.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kollmann, Robert, Zeno Enders, and Gernot J. Müller. 2011. Global Banking and International Business Cycles. European Economic Review 55 (3): 407–426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuvshinov, Dmitry. 2019. The Time Varying Risk Puzzle. University of Bonn, Working Paper.

  • Meller, Barbara, and Norbert Metiu. 2017. The Synchronization of Credit Cycles. Journal of Banking & Finance 82: 98–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michie, Ranald C. 1986. The London and New York stock Exchanges, 1850–1914. Journal of Economic History 46 (1): 171–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miranda-Agrippino, Silvia, and Hélene Rey. 2015. World Asset Markets and the Global Financial Cycle. NBER Working Paper 21722.

  • Obstfeld, Maurice. 2014. Trilemmas and Trade-Offs: Living with Financial Globalization. BIS Working Paper 480.

  • Obstfeld, Maurice, Jay C. Shambaugh, and Alan M. Taylor. 2004. Monetary Sovereignty, Exchange Rates, and Capital Controls: The Trilemma in the Interwar Period. IMF Staff Papers 51 (1): 75–108.

    Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld, Maurice, Jay C. Shambaugh, and Alan M. Taylor. 2005. The Trilemma in History: Tradeoffs Among Exchange Rates, Monetary Policies, and Capital Mobility. Review of Economics and Statistics 87 (3): 423–438.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld, Maurice, Jay C. Shambaugh, and Alan M. Taylor. 2010. Financial Stability, the Trilemma, and International Reserves. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2 (2): 57–94.

    Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld, Maurice, and Alan M. Taylor. 2004. Global Capital Markets: Integration, Crisis, and Growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Quinn, Dennis P., and Hans-Joachim Voth. 2008. A Century of Global Equity Market Correlations. American Economic Review 98 (2): 535–540.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rigobon, Roberto, and Brian Sack. 2004. The Impact of Monetary Policy on Asset Prices. Journal of Monetary Economics 51 (8): 1553–1575.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schularick, Moritz, and Alan M. Taylor. 2012. Credit Booms Gone Bust: Monetary Policy, Leverage Cycles and Financial Crises, 1870–2008. American Economic Review 102 (2): 1029–1061.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schüler, Yves Stephan, Paul Hiebert, and Tuomas A. Peltonen. 2015. Characterising the Financial Cycle: A Multivariate and Time-Varying Approach. ECB Working Paper 1846.

  • Shambaugh, Jay C. 2004. The Effect of Fixed Exchange Rates on Monetary Policy. Quarterly Journal of Economics 119 (1): 301–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shiller, Robert J. 1981a. Do Stock Prices Move Too Much to be Justified by Subsequent Changes in Dividends? American Economic Review 71 (3): 421–436.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shiller, Robert J. 1981b. The Use of Volatility Measures in Assessing Market Efficiency. Journal of Finance 36 (2): 291–304.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shiller, Robert J. 2000. Irrational Exuberance. Wiley Online Library.

  • Shin, Hyun Song. 2012. Global Banking Glut and Loan Risk Premium. IMF Economic Review 60 (2): 155–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ueda, Kozo. 2012. Banking Globalization and International Business Cycles: Cross-Border Chained Credit Contracts and Financial Accelerators. Journal of International Economics 86 (1): 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ward, Felix. 2018. Global Risk Taking, Exchange Rates, and Monetary Policy. Working Paper.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Òscar Jordà.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Comments and suggestions from the conference organizers, the editor, and referees have helped improve the paper. Generous support from the Institute for New Economic Thinking, the Bundesministerium für Bildung und Forschung (BMBF), and the Volkswagen Foundation supported our work. We are grateful for their support. The views expressed in this paper are the sole responsibility of the authors and to not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or the Federal Reserve System.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Global Averages

Fig. 14
figure 14

Global average cycles. Notes: Global means. All series were detrended with a Baxter–King filter isolating cycles in the 2- to 32-year period range. The equity return premium series and interest rate series are depicted in levels. Outliers have been dropped from the graph in order to simplify the graphical exposition

Fig. 15
figure 15

Global average cycles (2–8 year cycles). Notes: Global means. All series were detrended with a Baxter–King filter isolating cycles in the 2–8-year period range. Outliers have been dropped from the graph in order to simplify the graphical exposition

Fig. 16
figure 16

Global average cycles (Hamilton filter). Notes: Global means. All series were detrended with the Hamilton filter, using lags one to four. Outliers have been dropped from the graph in order to simplify the graphical exposition

Appendix 2: Average Bilateral Correlations

Fig. 17
figure 17

Average bilateral correlation (2–8-year cycles). Notes: Spearman rank correlation coefficients based on 15-year rolling windows. 2–8-year period Baxter–King detrended series. Bars—95% cross-sectionally block-bootstrapped confidence bands

Fig. 18
figure 18

GDP-weighted average bilateral correlation (2–32-year cycles). Notes: Spearman rank correlation coefficients based on 15-year rolling windows. 2–32-year period Baxter–King detrended series. Bars—95% cross-sectionally block-bootstrapped confidence bands

Fig. 19
figure 19

Average bilateral correlation (Hamilton filter). Notes: Spearman rank correlation coefficients based on 15-year rolling windows. Hamilton filter detrended series (using lags one to four). Bars—95% cross-sectionally block-bootstrapped confidence bands

Fig. 20
figure 20

Average bilateral correlation (annual growth rates and first differences). Notes: Spearman rank correlation coefficients based on 15-year rolling windows. First differences (for the equity return premium and interest rates) and growth rates for all other variables. Bars—95% cross-sectionally block-bootstrapped confidence bands

Fig. 21
figure 21

Average bilateral correlation (Pearson correlation coefficient). Notes: Pearson correlation coefficients based on 15-year rolling windows. 2–32-year period Baxter–King detrended series. Bars—95% cross-sectionally block-bootstrapped confidence bands

Fig. 22
figure 22

Average bilateral correlation (USA). Notes: Spearman rank correlation coefficients based on 15-year rolling windows. 2–32-year period Baxter–King detrended series. Bars—95% cross-sectionally block-bootstrapped confidence bands. Average of all bilateral US country-pair correlations

Fig. 23
figure 23

Average bilateral concordance. Notes: Concordance based on 15-year rolling windows. Peaks defined as highest values in +/-2 year window. Minimum phase length 2 years. Minimum cycle length 4 years. Bars—95% cross-sectionally block-bootstrapped confidence bands

Fig. 24
figure 24

Regional correlations: Europe. Notes: Spearman rank correlation coefficients based on 15-year rolling windows. All series were detrended with a Baxter–King filter isolating cycles in the 2–32-year period range. Bars –95% cross-sectionally block-bootstrapped confidence bands

Fig. 25
figure 25

Regional correlations: Euro area. Notes: Spearman rank correlation coefficients based on 15-year rolling windows. All series were detrended with a Baxter–King filter isolating cycles in the 2–32-year period range. Bars—95% cross-sectionally block-bootstrapped confidence bands

Fig. 26
figure 26

Regional correlations: Scandinavia. Notes: Scandinavia: Denmark, Finland, Norway, and Sweden. Spearman rank correlation coefficients based on 15-year rolling windows. All series were detrended with a Baxter–King filter isolating cycles in the 2–32-year period range. Bars—95% cross-sectionally block-bootstrapped confidence bands

Fig. 27
figure 27

Regional correlations: Pacific. Notes: Pacific region: Australia, Canada, Japan, and United States. Spearman rank correlation coefficients based on 15-year rolling windows. All series were detrended with a Baxter–King filter isolating cycles in the 2–32-year period range. Bars—95% cross-sectionally block-bootstrapped confidence bands

Appendix 3: Equity Return Premium Covariance Decomposition

This section decomposes equity return premiums through a vector autoregression (VAR) decomposition in the spirit of Campbell (1991). The advantage of such decompositions over the comovement analyses presented so far is that they explicitly model investor expectations and thus do not require the equalization of ex ante expected values with ex post realized ones. A recent example for such a decomposition based on the long-run data we use is Kuvshinov (2018). In particular, we build on the two-country decomposition suggested by Ammer and Mei (1996). This approach attributes unexpected fluctuations in the current equity return premium of country i (\({\tilde{e}}_{t+1}^i\)) to news about future discounted dividends, risk-free rates and equity return premiums.

1.1 The Return Premium Model

Starting from the log gross equity return definition

$$\begin{aligned} h_{t+1} = log(P_{t+1} + D_{t+1}) - log(P_{t}), \end{aligned}$$
(15)

where P denotes the equity price and D the dividend paid. A first-order Taylor approximation yields

$$\begin{aligned} h_{t+1} \approx \delta _t - \rho \delta _{t+1} + \Delta d_{t+1} + k, \end{aligned}$$
(16)

where \(\Delta d\) denotes the first difference of the log of the dividend payment D, \(\delta \) is the dividend-price ratio, \(\rho \) is a (discount) factor smaller than 1 and k is a linearization constant (see Campbell and Shiller 1988). Solving (16) forwardFootnote 10, taking expectations and plugging the resulting expectation equations for \(\delta _{t}\) and \(\delta _{t+1}\) back into (16) results in the following expression for the unexpected change in the log real return on equity:

$$\begin{aligned} h_{t+1} - E_t h_{t+1} = (E_{t+1} - E_t) \left[ \sum _{k=0}^{\infty } \rho ^k \Delta d_{t+1+k} - \sum _{k=1}^{\infty } \rho ^k h_{t+1+k} \right] , \end{aligned}$$
(17)

where \(E_t\) is an expectation operator denoting expectations formed on the basis of information available through t. Put in terms of equity return premiums \(e_{t+1} := h_{t+1} - r_{t+1}\), where r denotes the log real interest rate, Eq. (17) can be rewritten as

$$\begin{aligned} e_{t+1} - E_t e_{t+1} = (E_{t+1} - E_t) \left[ \sum _{k=0}^{\infty } \rho ^k \Delta d_{t+1+k} - \sum _{k=0}^{\infty } \rho ^k r_{t+1+k} - \sum _{k=1}^{\infty } \rho ^k e_{t+1+k} \right] , \end{aligned}$$
(18)

or more compactly, for any country i

$$\begin{aligned} {\tilde{e}}_{t+1}^i = {\tilde{e}}_{d,t+1}^i - {\tilde{e}}_{r,t+1}^i - {\tilde{e}}_{e,t+1}^i. \end{aligned}$$
(19)

The general intuition behind Eq.  19 is that innovations in the equity return premium of country i can be decomposed into news about the discounted sum of future dividend streams, news about the discounted sum of future risk-free real interest rates, and news about the discounted sum of future equity return premiums. Thus, if the equity return premium increases, this is either due to news about higher future dividends, lower future risk-free rates or lower future return premiums.

Consider the same decomposition for another country j. In order to render real equity returns in j comparable to those in i it is necessary to introduce a real exchange rate term \({\tilde{e}}_{q,t+1}\):

$$\begin{aligned} {\tilde{e}}_{t+1}^j = {\tilde{e}}_{d,t+1}^j - {\tilde{e}}_{r,t+1}^j - {\tilde{e}}_{e,t+1}^j - {\tilde{e}}_{q,t+1}^j, \end{aligned}$$
(20)

where \({\tilde{e}}_{q,t+1} = (E_{t+1} - E_t) \sum _{k=0}^{\infty } \rho ^k q_{t+1+k}\) denotes news about the sum of future discounted log real exchange rates.Footnote 11

We are interested in characterizing the comovement of return premiums in countries i and j, \({\tilde{e}}_{t+1}^i\) and \({\tilde{e}}_{t+1}^j\). From Eqs. (19) and (20), it follows that the covariance in equity return premiums \(Cov({\tilde{e}}^i,{\tilde{e}}^j)\) can be decomposed as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} Cov({\tilde{e}}^i,{\tilde{e}}^j)&= Cov({\tilde{e}}^i_d,{\tilde{e}}^j_d) - Cov({\tilde{e}}^i_d,{\tilde{e}}^j_r) - Cov({\tilde{e}}^i_d,{\tilde{e}}^j_e) - Cov({\tilde{e}}^i_d,{\tilde{e}}^j_q) \\&\quad - Cov({\tilde{e}}^i_r,{\tilde{e}}^j_d) + Cov({\tilde{e}}^i_r,{\tilde{e}}^j_r) + Cov({\tilde{e}}^i_r,{\tilde{e}}^j_e) + Cov({\tilde{e}}^i_r,{\tilde{e}}^j_q) \\&\quad - Cov({\tilde{e}}^i_e,{\tilde{e}}^j_d) + Cov({\tilde{e}}^i_e,{\tilde{e}}^j_r) + Cov({\tilde{e}}^i_e,{\tilde{e}}^j_e) + Cov({\tilde{e}}^i_e,{\tilde{e}}^j_q). \end{aligned}$$
(21)

This decomposition allows us to analyze whether the rise in equity return premium comovement was due to a rise in the comovement of dividend news \(Cov({\tilde{e}}^i_d,{\tilde{e}}^j_d)\), risk-free rate news \(Cov({\tilde{e}}^i_r{\tilde{e}}^j_r)\), or return premium news \(Cov({\tilde{e}}^i_e,{\tilde{e}}^j_e)\).

Note that in contrast to the comovement analyses presented in the main text, which have looked at equity prices, the covariance analysis presented here directly looks at the comovement in equity return premiums. The results of the two approaches are comparable in that they both indicate the extent to which international comovement in equities can be accounted for by fundamentals—dividends and risk-free rates—and how much must be attributed to other factors—risk appetite, or news about future return premiums.

1.2 The VAR Model

In order to compute the variance decomposition (21), we need estimates of the various news terms in Eqs. (19) and (20). A VAR model serves this purpose. The assumption is that changes in expectations due to new information arriving between t and \(t+1\) can be isolated through the VAR model. We estimate bilateral VARs on the basis of the following variables: log equity return premiums \(e_{i,t}, e_{j,t}\), log real interest rates \(r_{i,t}, r_{j,t}\), dividend-price ratios \(\delta _{i,t}, \delta _{j,t}\) and the first differences of the log bilateral real exchange rate \(\Delta q_{t}\). Collecting these variables in the vector \(\varvec{z}_t = \begin{pmatrix} e_{t}^i&r_{t}^i&\delta _{t}^i&e_{t}^j&r_{t}^j&\delta _{t}^j&q_{t}^j \end{pmatrix}^T\) the VAR model for \(\varvec{z_{t+1}}\) in companion form is

$$\begin{aligned} \varvec{z}_{t+1} = \varvec{A} \varvec{z}_t + \varvec{\epsilon }_{t+1} \, , \end{aligned}$$
(22)

where \(\varvec{A}\) is the VAR parameter matrix and \(\varvec{\epsilon }\) contains the error terms. The inclusion of variables from countries i and j enables us to study the linkage between both countries.

The equity return premium model summarized by Eqs. (19) and (20) imposes a tight set of cross-equation restrictions on the VAR. On the basis of these and the estimated VAR, we compute each of the news components in Eqs. (19) and (20) for each bilateral country-pair ij. For this purpose, we define picking vectors \(\varvec{g}_k\) (row k of the identity matrix) that select the relevant rows from the VAR system:

$$\begin{aligned} \varvec{{\tilde{e}}}_{t+1}^m= & {} \varvec{g}_1^m \varvec{\epsilon }_{t+1} \, , \quad m=i,j \end{aligned}$$
(23)
$$\begin{aligned} \varvec{{\tilde{e}}}_{e,t+1}^m= & {} \varvec{g}_1^m \rho _m \varvec{A} (\varvec{I}-\rho _m \varvec{A})^{-1} \varvec{\epsilon }_{t+1} \, , \quad m=i,j \end{aligned}$$
(24)
$$\begin{aligned} \varvec{{\tilde{e}}}_{r,t+1}^m= & {} \varvec{g}_2^m (\varvec{I}-\rho _m \varvec{A})^{-1} \varvec{\epsilon }_{t+1} \, , \quad m=i,j \end{aligned}$$
(25)
$$\begin{aligned} \varvec{{\tilde{e}}}_{q,t+1}^j= & {} \varvec{g}_3^j (\varvec{I}-\rho _j \varvec{A})^{-1} \varvec{\epsilon }_{t+1} \, , \end{aligned}$$
(26)
$$\begin{aligned} \varvec{{\tilde{e}}}_{d,t+1}^i= & {} \varvec{{\tilde{e}}}_{t+1}^i + \varvec{{\tilde{e}}}_{r,t+1}^i + \varvec{{\tilde{e}}}_{e,t+1}^i \, , \end{aligned}$$
(27)
$$\begin{aligned} \varvec{{\tilde{e}}}_{d,t+1}^j= & {} \varvec{{\tilde{e}}}_{t+1}^j + \varvec{{\tilde{e}}}_{r,t+1}^j + \varvec{{\tilde{e}}}_{e,t+1}^j + \varvec{{\tilde{e}}}_{q,t+1}^j \, , \end{aligned}$$
(28)

We set \(\rho \) to 0.96.Footnote 12 We can use the thus calculated news components in order to determine whether correlated dividend news (\({\tilde{e}}_d\)), monetary policy news (\({\tilde{e}}_r\)) or news about future equity return premiums (\({\tilde{e}}_e\)) have historically been most important in driving the comovement in international equity return premiums.Footnote 13

1.3 Covariance Decomposition

Table 6 shows the covariance decomposition for a pre-WW2 sample, a post-WW2 sample, as well as a post-1980 sample zooming in on the period of high equity price synchronization. The top row states the equity return premium covariance in our sample, and all following rows state the median bilateral component covariances.

Clearly equity return premium covariance has increased over time, from 1.61 in the pre-WW2 sample to 1.99 in the post-WW2 sample, and 3.48 in the post-1980 sample. Among its components, dividend news covariance is the largest. However, dividend covariance has neither increased, nor decreased substantially over time. One covariance component that clearly increases over time is the covariance in news about future return premiums, which roughly doubles in size in the post-1980 sample.

Covariance in risk-free rate news exhibits a downward trend over time. This is consistent with many countries moving toward a floating exchange rate regime after the end of the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates. As a consequence, international risk-free rate covariance explains little of the covariance in return premiums after 1980. Finally, an absolute decrease in some cross-covariance terms, such as the covariance between dividends and risk-free rates, also contributed to the increase in equity return premium comovement.

Overall, the VAR decomposition confirms our earlier result, that neither dividends, nor risk-free rates can explain the late twentieth-century surge in equity comovement. Instead it is risk appetite or, put in terms of the terminology used here, revisions to expected future return premiums, that are the primary explanation for the increasing comovement of equities.

Table 6 Decomposition of the covariance in equity return premiums

1.4 International Response to US Risk-Free Rate Changes

Fig. 28
figure 28

Response to \(+1ppt\) US policy rate increase. Notes: Median bilateral impulse response functions to +1ppt increase in US interest rates. Dashed gray — US short-term real risk-free rate own response. \(95\%\) interval based on cross-sectional block-bootstrap procedure over bilateral country pairs

By extending the VAR framework introduced above, it becomes possible to trace the effects of US monetary policy on return premiums, dividend-price ratios and risk-free rates, within a framework that acknowledges that ex post realized variables can deviate from their ex ante expected counterparts. This is achieved by incorporating US interest rate policy innovations \( \Delta R^{US}_t\) into the VAR system (see Bernanke and Kuttner 2005):

$$\begin{aligned} \varvec{z}_{t+1} = \varvec{A} \varvec{z}_t + \varvec{\phi } \Delta {R}^{US}_t + \varvec{\epsilon }_{t+1}. \end{aligned}$$
(29)

As our indicator for US short-term rate innovations, we use the residuals from a Taylor rule regression of US real short-term rate changes on changes in US real per capita GDP, US CPI inflation, and US real stock prices, as well as one lag of each regressor. The responses of international equity return premiums, dividend-price ratios, and real short-term rates can then be calculated as \(\varvec{A}^k \varvec{\phi }\).

Figure 28 displays the resulting impulse response functions for the full sample, as well as the post-1980 sample of high equity return premium comovement. For the full sample dividends and risk-free rates react to US monetary policy innovations, but not equity return premiums. In contrast, after 1980, equity return premiums exhibit a marked response. International risk-free rates respond less after 1980, than before, while the dividend-price ratio responds similarly in the full- and the post-1980 samples.

In sum, these findings support the evidence presented earlier, which suggests that the effect of US monetary policy on international equity return premiums has gained strength in the past few decades.

1.5 Explaining the Reaction to US Risk-Free Rate Changes

We can also decompose the effect of US rate innovations on equity return premiums in order to determine whether US monetary policy affects international return premiums through revisions in expectations about future return premiums, dividends or risk-free rates. This can be achieved by multiplying equations (23) to (25) with \(\varvec{\phi }\), the vector describing the contemporaneous response of all variables in \(\varvec{z}\) to US risk-free rate innovations. Accordingly, the response of the return premium news of country i is

$$\begin{aligned} \varvec{g}_1^i \rho _i \varvec{A} (\varvec{I}-\rho _i \varvec{A})^{-1} \varvec{\phi }, \end{aligned}$$
(30)

and the response of real risk-free interest rate news is

$$\begin{aligned} \varvec{g}_2^i (\varvec{I}-\rho _i \varvec{A})^{-1} \varvec{\phi }. \end{aligned}$$
(31)

In accordance with Eq. (27), the response of the present value of expected future dividends is

$$\begin{aligned} \varvec{g}_1^i \varvec{\phi } + \varvec{g}_1^i \rho _i \varvec{A} (\varvec{I} -\rho _i \varvec{A})^{-1} \varvec{\phi } + \varvec{g}_2^i (\varvec{I}-\rho _i \varvec{A})^{-1} \varvec{\phi } . \end{aligned}$$
(32)

Table 7 displays the median response over all 16 country pairs for the full sample, and the post-1980 sample. The post-1980 results indicate that revisions in the expectation about future return premiums explain most of the current return premium response. News about dividends and risk-free rates plays smaller roles. In contrast, over the full sample revisions in the expectation about future dividends explains most of the current return premium response, while news about future returns and risk-free rates play a smaller role.

This confirms our earlier finding based on another methodology. The post-1980 increase in international equity comovement was driven by factors other than dividends and risk-free rates.

Table 7 The impact of US monetary policy on dividends, interest rates and future premiums

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Jordà, Ò., Schularick, M., Taylor, A.M. et al. Global Financial Cycles and Risk Premiums. IMF Econ Rev 67, 109–150 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-019-00077-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-019-00077-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation