Skip to main content

Demographics and the Behavior of Interest Rates

Abstract

Interest rates are very persistent. Modeling the persistent component of interest rates has important consequence for forecasting. Factor models of the term structure are restricted VAR models that project over a long-horizon the one-period risk-free rate to obtain yields at longer horizon as the sum of the expected future monetary policy and the term premia. The included factors are typically mean reverting and the equilibrium real rates are considered constant (think, for example, of the standard Taylor rule), partial adjustments to equilibrium yields are then used to rationalize the persistence in the observed data. As a result, the empirical models feature a very high level of persistence that makes long-horizon predictions inherently inaccurate. This paper relates the common persistent component of the U.S. term structure of interest rates to the age composition of population. The composition of age structure determines the equilibrium rate in the monetary policy rule and therefore the persistent component in one-period yields. Fluctuations in demographics are then transmitted to the whole-term structure via the expected policy rate components. We build an affine term structure model (ATSM) which exploits demographic information to capture the dynamics of yields and produce useful forecasts of bond yields and excess returns that provide economic value for long-term investors.

This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.

Figure 1

Notes: (a) US post-war nominal yields. The gray shaded area covers from the beginning of the first round of quantitative easing (2008Q3) to the end of the sample. Quarterly sample 1961Q3-2013Q4. (b) US post-war real yields. Real yields are computed as the nominal yields minus expected inflation, that is, the predicted inflation from an autoregressive model using growth rate of GDP deflator. The gray shaded area covers from the beginning of the first round of quantitative easing (2008Q3) to the end of the sample. Quarterly sample 1961Q3-2013Q4.

Figure 2

Notes. (a) Compares the middle-aged to young ratio, MY (inverted, right-scaled, solid dark gray line), Fama trend (dashed gray line with plus), that is, 5-year moving average of 1-year Treasury bond yield, CP trend, that is, 10-year moving average of core inflation (dashed light gray line) with 1-year Treasury bond nominal yield (solid black line). The gray shaded area covers from the beginning of the first round of quantitative easing (2008Q3) to the end of the sample. Quarterly sample 1966Q3–2013Q4. (b) Compares the middle-aged to young ratio, MY (inverted, right-scaled, solid dark gray line), Fama trend (dashed gray line with plus), i.e., 5-year moving average of 1-year Treasury bond yield, CP trend, i.e., 10-year moving average of core inflation (dashed light gray line) with 1-year Treasury bond real yield (solid black line). The gray shaded area covers from the beginning of the first round of quantitative easing (2008Q3) to the end of the sample. Quarterly sample 1966Q3–2013Q4.

Figure 3

Note: The gray shaded area covers from the beginning of the first round of quantitative easing (2008Q3) to the end of the sample. Quarterly sample 1961Q1-2013Q4.

Figure 4

Notes: This figure plots the time series of bond yields (maturity: 3 month, 1, 2, 3, 4, 5 year) along with those dynamically simulated series from the benchmark Macro ATSM (dashed light gray line) and Demographic ATSM (solid dark gray line). The affine models with time-varying risk premia are estimated over the full sample and dynamically solved from the first observation onward. The gray shaded area covers from the beginning of the first round of quantitative easing (2008Q3) to the end of the sample. Quarterly sample 1964Q1-2013Q4.

Figure 5

Notes: This figure plots the in-sample estimated values (1964Q1–2013Q4) and out-of-sample predictions (2014Q1–2045Q4) of 3-month (reported in the upper panel) and 5-year (reported in the lower panel) yields. The Demographic ATSM (solid dark gray lines) and Macro ATSM (dashed light gray lines) are estimated over the full-sample 1964Q1–2013Q4. Using the estimated model parameters, models are solved dynamically forward starting from 1964Q1. The black dashed lines are in-sample mean of associated yields, and the vertical dashed line shows the end of in-sample estimation period. Quarterly sample 1964Q1–2013Q4.

Figure 6

Notes: This figure plots the middle-aged young (MY) ratio and its long-run projections based on alternative scenarios for the fertility rate and foreign holdings. The MY ratio (solid black line) is based on annual reports of BoC, while MY_1.7 (solid gray line), MY_2.1 (dashed black line), and MY_2.7 (dashed gray line) in Panel A are predicted in 1975 under 1.7, 2.1, and 2.7 fertility rates, respectively. All the projection information in Panel A is from BoC’s 1975 population estimation and projections report. Panel B projections are based on authors’ calculation from New York Fed’s report on foreign portfolio holdings of U.S. Securities (April 2013).

Figure 7

Notes: This figure shows simulated t-statistics on MY ratio which is obtained from an autoregressive model where the dependent variable is an artificial series bootstrapped (5000 simulations) from an autoregressive model for both nominal and real 3-month rates. The estimated t-statistics is the observed value of the t-statistics on MY ratio in an autoregressive model for the actual nominal or real 3-month rate augmented with MY ratio.

Notes

  1. “... adequate preparation for the coming demographic transition may well involve significant adjustments in our patterns of consumption, work effort, and saving...” Chairman Ben S. Bernanke, Before The Washington Economic Club, Washington, D.C., October 4, 2006. Also, research agenda questions (Theme 5) stated on Bank of England website stresses the importance of secular trends, in particular demographics, in determining equilibrium interest rates.

  2. When young adults, who are net borrowers, and the retired, who are dissavers, dominate the economy, savings decline and interest rates rise. The idea is certainly not a new one as it can be traced in the work of Wicksell (1936), Keynes and Maynard (1936), Modigliani and Brumberg (1954), but it has received relatively little attention in the recent literature.

  3. In principle, there are many alternative choices for the demographic variable, MY. However, using a proxy derived from a model is consistent with economic theory (Giacomini and Ragusa, 2014) and reduces the risk of a choice driven by data mining. Importantly, MY is meant to capture the relative weights of active savers investing in financial markets. Our results are robust to an alternative specification of the demographic variable, middle-aged to old (MO) ratio, another variable consistent with the GMQ model.

  4. The literature is vast, few related examples are Ang and Piazzesi (2003), Diebold et al (2006), Gallmeyer et al (2005), Hordahl et al (2006), Rudebusch and Wu (2008), Bekaert et al (2003).

  5. The Bureau of Census currently publishes, on its website, the projections for the age structure of the population with a forecasting horizon up to fifty years ahead and historical Census reports back to 1950 are available to avoid look-ahead bias.

  6. While the nominal short rate is directly observable, the real rate depends on how the expected inflation is modeled. Here, we predict the inflation from an autoregressive model using growth rate of GDP deflator. Our main analysis will be based on observable nominal rates, since the demographic channel affects the nominal rates via the (unobserved) real rates regardless of different inflation specifications (Gozluklu et al, 2015).

  7. There are other alternative views in the literature which argue for a unit root in the spot rates (Dewachter and Lyrio, 2006; Christensen et al, 2011; Hamilton et al, 2015) or suggest a near unit root process to model the persistent component (Cochrane and Piazzesi, 2005; Jardet, Monfort and Pegoraro, 2013; Osterrieder et al, 2012).

  8. Theoretical models suggest a link between equilibrium rate and growth in the economy, measured either via output or consumption growth. However, empirical evidence on economic fundamentals driving equilibrium rate is at best weak (Hamilton et al, 2015).

  9. Earlier papers (Bai and Perron, 2003; Rapach and Wohar, 2005) document structural breaks in the mean real interest rates.

  10. In a nutshell, high policy inertia should determine high predictability of the short-term interest rates, even after controlling for macroeconomic uncertainty related to the determinants of the central bank reaction function. This is not in line with the empirical evidence based on forward rates, future rates (in particular federal funds futures), and VAR models.

  11. Life-cycle investment hypothesis suggests that agents should borrow when young, invest for retirement when middle-aged, and live off their investment once they are retired.

  12. Recent literature also shows that consumption smoothing across time rather than the risk management across states is the primary concern of the households (Rampini and Viswanathan, 2014).

  13. We adopt Cochrane and Piazzesi (2005) notation for log bond prices: \(p_{t}^{(n)}=\log\) price of n-year discount bond at time t. The continuously compounded spot rate is then \(y_{t}^{(n)}\equiv -\frac{1}{n} p_{t}^{(n)}\)

  14. Note that under the assumption of perfectly stationary demographic structure, the relative cohort size, middle-aged over young population is the same as the middle-aged over retired population.

  15. The implications of the evidence for stock market predictability are further investigated by Favero et al (2011).

  16. Ang et al (2008) have solved the identification problem of estimating two unobservables, real rates, and inflation risk premia, from only nominal yields by using a no-arbitrage term structure model that imposes restrictions on the nominal yields. These pricing restrictions identify the dynamics of real rates (and the inflation risk premia).

  17. Over a longer sample period 1900Q1–2013Q4, the demographic variable MY explains about 15 percent of the variation in real short rates once we use a AR(1) model with stochastic volatility to extract the expected inflation.

  18. One can conjecture a world with endogenous fertility choice (Barro and Becker, 1989; Wang et al, 1994). However, in our sample, a Granger causality test between real interest rates and the MY ratio suggests that the demographic variable Granger causes real bond yields, and not the other way around.

  19. The Bureau of Census website provides projections for demographics variable up to 2050 and the current 5-year yield depends on the values of MY over the next five years.

  20. One-year Treasury bond yields are taken from Gurkaynak et al,'s dataset. Middle-young ratio data are available at annual frequencies from Bureau of Census (BoC) and it has been interpolated to obtain quarterly series.

  21. Improvement in mortality rates that have generated over the last forty years difference between actual population and projected population are mostly concentrated in older ages, after 65.

  22. The results are robust when we construct a smaller panel with balanced data. The demographic data are collected from World Bank database.

  23. Bond yield are collected from Global Financial data. Long-term bond yields are 10-year yields for most of the countries, except Japan (7-year), Finland, South Korea, Singapore (5-year), Mexico (3-year), and Hong Kong (2-year).

  24. We thank an anonymous referee for pointing out that for some countries the domestic bond markets may be less important for life-cycle investment behavior, e.g., households from the emerging markets may instead demand foreign assets, in particular, U.S. securities (dollarization).

  25. The report provides annual forecasts from 1975 to 2000 and five-year forecasts from 2000 to 2050.

  26. We do not have age structure data for Cayman Islands, Middle East countries, and rest of the world. So, we account for 60 percent of foreign bond holdings as of June 2012. Source: Demographic data 1960–2000 from World Bank Population Statistics, Data 2011–2050 from U.S. Census International Database.

  27. The t-statistics MY\(_{t}\) coefficient in the OLS regression of the 3-month rate on its own lag and the demographic variable.

  28. The probability of observing a t-statistics of −3.02 on the coefficient on MY\(_{t}\) is 0.032 for the nominal rate and a t-statistics of −3.12 on the coefficient on MY\(_{t}\) is 0.018 for the real rate.

References

  • Abel, Andrew B., 2001, “Will Bequests Attenuate the Predicted Meltdown in Stock Prices When Baby Boomers Retire?” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 83, pp. 589–595.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aksoy, Yunus, Henrique S. Basso, Tobias Grasl, and Ron P. Smith, 2015, "Demographic Structure and Macroeconomic Trend,” Working Paper (Birkbeck, Department of Economics, Mathematics & Statistics).

  • Ang, Andrew and Geert Bekaert, 2002, “Regime switches in interest rates,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, Vol. 20, No. 2, pp. 163–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ang, Andrew and Monika Piazzesi, 2003, “A No-arbitrage vector autoregression of term structure dynamics with macroeconomic and latent variables,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 50, No. 4, pp. 745–787.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ang, Andrew, Geert Bekaert, and Min Wei, 2008, “The term structure of real rates and expected inflation,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 53, No. 2, pp. 797-849.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ang, Andrew, Sen Dong, and Monika Piazzesi, 2007, “No-arbitrage Taylor rules,” NBER Working Paper No. 13448 (Cambridge, Massachusetts, National Bureau of Economic Research).

  • Ang, Andrew and Angela Maddaloni, 2005, “Do demographic changes affect risk premiums? Evidence from international data,” Journal of Business, Vol. 78, No. 1, pp. 341–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bakshi, Gurdip S. and Zhiwu Chen, 1994, “Baby boom, population aging, and capital markets,” Journal of Business, Vol. 67, No. 2, pp. 165–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balduzzi, Pierluigi, Sanjiv Ranjan Das, and Silverio Foresi, 1998, “The central tendency: A second factor in bond yields,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 80, No. 1, pp. 62–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bai, Jushan and Pierre Perron, 2003, “Computation and analysis of multiple structural change models,” Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 18, No. 1, pp. 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bali, Turan, Massoud Heidari, and Liuren Wu, 2009, “Predictability of interest rates and interest-rate portfolios,” Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, Vol. 27, No. 4, pp. 517–527.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barillas, Francisco, 2011, “Can we exploit predictability in bond markets?” Working Paper (Emory University).

  • Barro, Robert and Gary Becker,1989, “ Fertility choice in a model of economic growth,” Econometrica Vol. 57, No. 2., pp. 481–501.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bekaert, Geert, Seonghoon Cho, and Antonio Moreno, 2003, “New-Keynesian macroeconomics and the term structure,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 42, No. 1, pp. 33–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bekaert, Geert and Eric Engstrom, 2010, “Inflation and the stock market: understanding the ’Fed model’,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 57, pp. 278–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergantino, Steven M., 1998, “Life cycle investment behavior, demographics, and asset prices,” PhD Dissertation (Massachusetts Institute of Technology).

  • Bernanke, Ben, 2006, “The coming demographic transition: Will we treat future generations fairly?” The full text of the speech is available at Federal Reserve’s website: http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20061004a.htm.

  • Bernanke, Ben and Jean Boivin, 2003, “Monetary policy in a data-rich environment,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 50, pp. 525–546.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom, David E., David Canning and Bryan Graham (2003). “Longevity and Life-cycle Savings.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol. 105, No. 3, pp. 319–338.

  • Brooks, Robin, 1998, “Asset markets and savings effects of demographic transitions,” Doctoral Dissertation (Yale University, Department of Economics).

  • Campbell, John Y. and Tuomo Vuolteenaho, 2004, “Inflation illusion and stock prices,” American Economic Review, Vol. 94, No. 2, pp. 19–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carriero, Andrea and Raffaella Giacomini, 2011, “How useful are no-arbitrage restrictions for forecasting the term structure of interest rates?” Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 164, pp. 21–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Ren-Raw and Louis Scott, 1993, “Maximum likelihood estimation for a multi-factor equilibrium model of the term structure of interest rates,” Journal of Fixed Income, Vol. 3, No. 3, pp. 14–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christensen, Jens H.E., Francis X. Diebold, and Glenn D. Rudebusch, 2011, “The affine arbitrage-free class of Nelson-Siegel term structure models,” Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 164, No. 1, pp. 4–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cieslak, Anna, and Pavol Povala, 2015, “Expected Returns in Treasury Bonds,” Review of Financial Studies.

  • Clarida, Richard, Jordi Galì, and Mark Gertler, 2000, “Monetary policy rules and macroeconomic stability: Evidence and some theory,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 115, No. 1, pp. 147–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, Todd E. and Kenneth D. West, 2006, “Using out-of-sample mean squared prediction errors to test the martingale difference hypothesis,” Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 135, pp. 155–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———, 2007, “Approximately normal tests for equal predictive accuracy in nested models,” Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 138, pp. 291–311.

  • Cochrane, John. H. and Monika Piazzesi, 2005, “Bond risk premia,” American Economic Review, Vol. 95, pp. 138–160.

  • D’Agostino, Antonello, Surico, Paolo, 2012, “A century of inflation forecasts,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 94, No. 4, pp. 1097–1106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dai, Qiang, Kenneth J. Singleton, 2002, “Expectation puzzles, time-varying risk premia, and affine models of the term structure,” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 63, pp. 415–441.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, E Philip, Christine Li, 2003, “Demographics and financial asset prices in the major industrial economies,” Working Paper (West London, Brunel University).

  • DellaVigna, Stefano and Joshua M. Pollet, 2007, “Demographics and industry returns,” American Economic Review, Vol. 97, No. 5, pp. 1167–1702.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dewachter, Hans and Marco Lyrio, 2006, “Macro factors and the term structure of interest rates,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 38, pp. 119–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diebold, Francis X. and Glenn D. Rudebusch, 2013, “Yield curve modeling and forecasting: The Dynamic Nelson-Siegel approach,” (Princeton University Press).

  • Diebold, Francis X., Glenn D. Rudebusch, and S. Boragan Aruoba, 2006, “The macroeconomy and the yield curve: A dynamic latent factor approach,” Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 131, pp. 309–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diebold, Francis X. and Canlin Li, 2006, “Forecasting the term structure of government bond yields,” Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 130, No. 2, pp. 337–364

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Driscoll, John C, and Aart C. Kraay, 1998, “Consistent covariance matrix estimation with spatially dependent panel data,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 80, pp. 549–560.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duffee, Gregory R., 2002, “Term premia and interest rate forecasts in affine models,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 57, No. 1, pp. 405–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———, 2011, “Forecasting with the term structure: The role of no-arbitrage restrictions,” Working Paper (the Johns Hopkins University, Department of Economics).

  • ———, 2012, “Forecasting interest rates,” Handbook of Economic Forecasting, Vol. 2, pp. 385–426.

  • Duffie, Darrell, Rui Kan, and others, 1996, “A yield-factor model of interest rates,” Mathematical Finance, Vol. 6, pp. 379–406.

  • Eggertsson, Gauti B., and Neil R. Mehrotra, 2014, “A model of secular stagnation,” NBER Working Paper No. 20574 (Cambridge, Massachusetts, National Bureau of Economic Research).

  • Eichengreen, Barry, 2015, “Secular Stagnation: The Long View,” NBER Working Paper No. w20836 (Cambridge, Massachusetts, National Bureau of Economic Research).

  • Evans, Martin D. D., 2003, “Real risk, inflation risk, and the term structure,” Economic Journal, Vol. 113, No. 487, pp. 345–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, George W. and Seppo Honkapohja, 2003, “Adaptive learning and monetary policy design,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 35, pp. 1045–1072.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, Eugene F., 2006, “The behavior of interest rates,” Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 19, No. 2, pp. 359–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Favero, Carlo A., Arie E. Gozluklu, and Andrea Tamoni, 2011, “Demographic trends, the dividend-price ratio and the predictability of long-run stock market returns,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, Vol. 46, No. 5, pp. 1493–1520.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Favero, Carlo. A., Linlin Niu, and Luca Sala, 2012, “Term structure forecasting: No-arbitrage restrictions versus large information set,” Journal of Forecasting, Vol. 31, No. 2, pp. 124–156.

  • Feldstein, Martin S., 2011, “What is Next for the Dollar?” NBER Working Paper No. w17260 (Cambridge, Massachusetts, National Bureau of Economic Research).

  • Gallmeyer, Michael F., Burton Hollifield, and Stanley E. Zin, 2005, “Taylor rules, McCallum rules, and the term structure of interest rates,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 52, No. 5, pp. 921–950.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gargano, Antonio, Davide Pettenuzzo, and Allan G. Timmermann, 2014, “Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy,” Working Paper (University of Melbourne).

  • Geanakoplos, John, Michael Magill, and Martine Quinzii, 2004, “Demography and the long run Behavior of the stock market,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activities, Vol. 1, pp. 241–325.

  • Giacomini, Raffaella and Giuseppe Ragusa, 2014, “Theory-coherent forecasting,” Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 182, No. 1, pp. 145–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giacomini, Raffaella, and Halbert White, 2006, “Tests of conditional predictive ability,” Econometrica, Vol. 74, pp. 1545–1578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giannone, Domenico, Michele Lenza, and Giorgio E. Primiceri, 2014, “Priors for the long run,” manuscript.

  • Goodhart, Charles, and Philipp Erfurth, 2014, “Demography and economics: Look past the past,” Global Macro Analyst (New York, Morgan Stanley).

    Google Scholar 

  • Goyal, Amit, 2004, “Demographics, stock market flows, and stock returns,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, Vol. 39, No. 1, pp. 115–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goyal, Amit and Ivo Welch, 2008, “A comprehensive look at the empirical performance of equity premium prediction,” Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 21, No. 4, pp. 1455–1508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gozluklu, Arie E., and Annaig Morin, 2015, “Stocks vs. bond yields, and demographic fluctuations,” Working Paper (University of Warwick).

  • Gray, Stephen F., 1996, “Modeling the conditional distribution of interest rates as a regime-switching process,” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 42, pp. 26–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guidolin, Massimo, and Daniel L. Thornton, 2011, “Predictions of short-term rates and the expectations hypothesis, Working Paper (Manchester Business School).

  • Gurkaynak, Refet S., Brian P. Sack, and Jonathan H. Wright, 2006, “The U.S. Treasury Yield Curve: 1961 to The Present,” FEDS Working Paper, No. 2006-28.

  • ———, 2007, “The U.S. Treasury Yield Curve: 1961 to The Present,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 54, No. 8, pp. 2291–2304.

  • Hamilton, James D., Ethan S. Harris, Jan Hatzius, and Kenneth D. West, 2015, “The equilibrium real funds rate: Past, present and the future,” Working Paper (University of California at San Diego).

  • Hansen, Alvin, 1938, speech published as Hansen, A. H., 1939, “Economic progress and declining population growth,” American Economic Review, Vol. 29, pp. 1–15.

  • Hansen, Lars Peter and Robert J. Hodrick, 1980, “Forward exchange rates as optimal predictors of future spot rates: An econometric analysis,” The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 88, pp. 829–853.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hordahl, Peter, Oreste Tristani, and David Vestin, 2006, “A joint econometric model of macroeconomic and term structure dynamics,” Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 131, pp. 405–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang, Jing-zhi and Zhan Shi, 2012, “Determinants of bond risk premia,” Working Paper (Penn State University).

  • Jardet, Caroline, Alain Monfort, and Fulvio Pegoraro, 2013, “No-arbitrage near-cointegrated VAR (p) term structure models, term premia and GDP growth,” Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 37, No. 2, pp. 389–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Juselius, Mikael and Elod Takats, 2015, “Can demography affect inflation and monetary policy?” Working Paper (Bank for International Settlements).

  • Keynes, John Maynard, 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (London: Macmillan).

    Google Scholar 

  • Lander, Joel, Athanasios Orphanides, Martha Douvogiannis, 1997, “Earnings forecasts and the predictability of stock returns: Evidence from trading the S&P,” Journal of Portfolio Management, Vol. 23, pp. 24−35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laubach, Thomas, John C. Williams, 2003, “Measuring the natural rate of interest,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 85, No. 4, pp. 1063–1070.

  • Lindh, Thomas and Bo Malmberg, 2000, “Can age structure forecast inflation trends,” Journal of Economics and Business, Vol 52, pp. 31–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ludvigson, Sydney and Serena Ng, 2009, “Macro factors in bond risk premia,” Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 22, No. 12, pp. 5027–5067.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malmendier, Ulrike and Stefan Nagel, 2016, “Learning from inflation experiences,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 131, No. 1, pp. 53–87.

  • McMillan, Henry and Jerome B. Baesel, 1988, “The role of demographic factors in interest rate forecasting,” Managerial and Decision Economics, Vol. 9, No. 3, pp. 187–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani, Franco and Richard Brumberg, 1954, “Utility Analysis and the Consumption Function: An Interpretation of Cross-Section Data,” In K. Kurihara ed. Post Keynesian Economics (Rutgers University Press).

  • Moench, Emanuel, 2008, “Forecasting the Yield Curve in a data-rich environment: a no-arbitrage factor-augmented VAR approach,” Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 146, pp. 26–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Orphanides, Athanasios and John C. Williams, 2007, “Robust monetary policy with imperfect knowledge,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 54, pp. 1406–1435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Osterrieder, Daniela, Peter C. Schotman, 2012, “The volatility of long-term bond returns persistent interest shocks and time-varying risk premiums,” Netspar Working Paper.

  • Pericoli, Marcello and Marco Taboga, 2008, “Canonical term-structure models with observable factors and the dynamics of bond risk premia,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 40, No. 7, pp. 1471–1488.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pescatori, Andrea and Jarkko Turunen, 2015, “Lower for longer: Natural rates in the United States” IMF Working Paper.

  • Poterba, James M., 2001, “Demographic structure and asset returns,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 83, No. 4, pp. 565–584.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rampini, Adriano A., S. Viswanathan, 2014, “Household risk management,” Working Paper (Duke University).

  • Rapach, David E. and Mark E. Wohar, 2005, “Regime changes in international real interest rates: Are they a monetary phenomenon?,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 37, No. 5, pp. 887–906.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rudebusch, Glenn D. and Tao Wu, 2008, “A macro-finance model of the term structure, monetary policy, and the economy,” Economic Journal, Vol. 118, pp. 906–926.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rudebusch, Glenn D., 2002, “Term structure evidence on interest-rate smoothing and monetary policy inertia,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 49, pp. 1161–1187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sarno, Lucio, Paul Schneider, and Christian Wagner, 2014, “The economic value of predicting bond risk premia: Can anything beat the expectations hypothesis?,” Working Paper (Cass Business School).

  • Soderlind, Paul, Ulf Soderstrom, and Anders Vredin, 2005, “Dynamic Taylor rules and the predictability of interest rates,” Macroeconomics Dynamics, Vol. 9, pp. 412–428.

    Google Scholar 

  • Summers, Larry, 2014, “US economic prospects: Secular stagnation, hysteresis and the zero lower bound,” Business Economics, Vol. 49, pp. 65–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svensson, Lars EO, 1997, “Inflation forecast targeting: Implementing and monitoring inflation targets,” European Economic Review, Vol. 41, pp. 1111–1146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, John B., 1993, “Discretion versus policy rules in practice,” Canergie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 39, pp. 195–214.

  • Thornton, Daniel L. and Giorgio Valente, 2012, “Out-of-sample predictions of bond excess returns and forward Rates: An asset allocation perspective,” Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 25, No. 10, pp. 3141−3168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, Ping, Chong K. Yip, and Carol A. Scotese, 1994, “ Fertility choice and economic growth: Theory and evidence,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 76, No. 2, pp. 255−266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wicksell, Knut, 1936, Interest and Prices. Translation of 1898, edition by R.F. Kahn (London, Macmillan).

  • Woodford, Michael, 2001, “The Taylor rule and optimal monetary policy,” American Economic Review, Vol. 91, pp. 232-237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———, 2003, Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy (Princeton University Press).

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Carlo A. Favero.

Additional information

* Carlo Favero holds a D.Phil. from Oxford University. He is a full professor of Deptment of Finance at Bocconi University and become Head of department in 2013. He is a research fellow of CEPR in the International Macroeconomics programme. He is president of IGIER at Bocconi University and a member of the scientific committee of CIDE. He has been advisor to the Italian Ministry of Treasury and consulting the European Commission, the World Bank and the European Central Bank; his email address is: carlo.favero@unibocconi.it. Arie Gozluklu is an Associate Professor of Finance at the University of Warwick. His research focuses on empirical asset pricing, international finance and market microstructure. His work has been published in Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, Journal of Financial Markets and Financial Management. He has a master’s degree in economics from Pompeu Fabra and a Ph.D. from Bocconi University. His research has been presented in international conferences including European Finance Association, China International Conference in Finance, NBER Summer Institute and Banque de France; his email address is: arie.gozluklu@wbs.ac.uk. Haoxi Yang is an Assistant Professor of School of Finance at Nankai University. Her primary research interests are asset pricing, financial econometrics and macro-finance. Her research has been presented at conferences organized by the Society for Financial Econometrics (SoFiE), the Financial Management Association (FMA), European Economic Association (EEA), China International Conference in Finance (CICF). She holds a Ph.D. in Finance from Bocconi University; her email address is: haoxi.yang@outlook.com.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (PDF 61 kb)

Appendices

Appendix A: Derivation of Demographic ATSM

We consider the following model specification for pricing bonds with macro and demographic factors:

$$\begin{gathered} y_{t}^{{(n)}} = - \frac{1}{n}\left( {A_{n} + B_{n}^{\prime } X_{t} + \Gamma _{n} {\text{MY}}_{t}^{n} } \right) + \varepsilon _{{t,t + 1}}\quad \varepsilon _{{t,t + n}} \sim N(0,\sigma _{n}^{2} )\hfill\\X_{t} = \mu + \Phi X_{{t - 1}} + \nu _{t}\quad \nu _{t} \sim i.i.d.N(0,\Omega ) \hfill \\ y_{t}^{{(1/4)}} = \delta _{0} + {\mathbf{\delta }}_{1}^{\prime } X_{t} + \delta _{2} {\text{MY}}_{t} \hfill \\ \Lambda _{t} = \lambda _{0} + \lambda _{1} X_{t} \hfill \\ m_{{t + 1}} = \exp ( - y_{t}^{{(1)}} - \frac{1}{2}\Lambda _{t}^{\prime } \Omega \Lambda _{t} - \Lambda _{t}^{\prime } v_{{t + 1}} ) \hfill \\ P_{t}^{{(n)}} \equiv \left[ {\frac{1}{{1 + Y_{{t,t + n}} }}} \right]^{n} ,{\mkern 1mu} y_{t}^{{(n)}} \equiv \ln \left( {1 + Y_{t}^{{(n)}} } \right) \hfill \\ \Gamma _{n} {\text{MY}}_{t}^{n} \equiv \left[ {\gamma _{0}^{n} ,\gamma _{1}^{n} \cdots ,\gamma _{{n - 1}}^{n} } \right] \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{\text{MY}}_{t} } \\ {{\text{MY}}_{{t + 1}} } \\ \vdots \\ {{\text{MY}}_{{t + n - 1}} } \\ \end{array} } \right] \quad X_{t} = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} f_{t}^{\pi }\\ f_{t}^{x} \\ {f_{t}^{{u,1}} } \hfill \\ {f_{t}^{{u,2}} } \hfill \\ {f_{t}^{{u,3}} } \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right] \hfill \\ \end{gathered}$$

Bond prices can be recursively computed as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} P_{t}^{{(n)}} & = E_{t} [m_{{t + 1}} P_{{t + 1}}^{{(n - 1)}} ] = E_{t} [m_{{t + 1}} m_{{t + 2}} P_{{t + 2}}^{{(n - 2)}} ] \\ & = E_{t} [m_{{t + 1}} m_{{t + 2}} \cdots m_{{t + n}} P_{{t + n}}^{{(0)}} ] = E_{t} [m_{{t + 1}} m_{{t + 2}} \cdots m_{{t + n}} 1] \\ & = E_{t} \left[ {\exp \left( {\mathop {\mathop \sum \limits^{{n - 1}} }\limits_{{i = 0}} \left( { - y_{{t + i,t + i + 1}} - \frac{1}{2}\Lambda _{{t + i}}^{\prime } \Omega \Lambda _{{t + i}} - \Lambda _{{t + i}}^{\prime } \nu _{{t + i + 1}} } \right)} \right)} \right] \\ & = E_{t} [\exp (A_{n} + B_{n}^{\prime } X_{t} + \Gamma _{n}^{\prime } {\text{MY}}_{t}^{n} )] = E_{t} \left[ {\exp \left( { - ny_{t}^{{(n)}} } \right)} \right] \\ & = E_{t}^{Q} \left[ {\exp \left( { - \mathop {\mathop \sum \limits^{{n - 1}} }\limits_{{i = 0}} y_{{t + i}}^{{(1)}} } \right)} \right], \\ \end{aligned}$$

where \(E_{t}^{Q}\) denotes the expectation under the risk-neutral probability measure, under which the dynamics of the state vector \(X_{t}\) are characterized by the risk-neutral vector of constants \(\mu ^{Q}\) and by the autoregressive matrix \(\Phi ^{Q}\)

$$\mu ^{Q}=\mu -\Omega \lambda _{0}\quad\text { and }\quad\Phi ^{Q}=\Phi -\Omega \lambda _{1}$$

To derive the coefficients of the model, let us start with \(n=1\):

$$P_{t}^{(1)}=\exp (-y_{t}^{(1/4)})=\exp (-\delta _{0}-\delta _{1}^{\prime } X_{t}-\delta _{2}\text {MY}_{t})$$

\(A_{1}=-\delta _{0}\), \(B_{1}=-\delta _{1}\) and \(\Gamma _{1}=\gamma _{0} ^{1}=-\delta _{2}\), Then for \(n+1,\)we have \(P_{t}^{(n+1)}=E_{t}[m_{t+1} P_{t+1}^{(n)}]\)

$$\begin{gathered} = E_{t} [\exp ( - y_{t}^{{(1/4)}} - \frac{1}{2}\Lambda _{t}^{\prime } \Omega \Lambda _{t} - \Lambda _{t}^{\prime } \nu _{{t + 1}} )\exp (A_{n} + B_{n}^{\prime } X_{{t + 1}} + \Gamma _{n} {\text{MY}}_{{t + 1}}^{n} )] \hfill \\ = \exp ( - y_{t}^{{(1/4)}} - \frac{1}{2}\Lambda _{t}^{\prime } \Omega \Lambda _{t} + A_{n} )E_{t} [\exp ( - \Lambda _{t}^{\prime } \nu _{{t + 1}} + B_{n}^{\prime } X_{{t + 1}} + \Gamma _{n} {\text{MY}}_{{t + 1}}^{n} )] \hfill \\ = \exp ( - y_{t}^{{(1/4)}} - \frac{1}{2}\Lambda _{t}^{\prime } \Omega \Lambda _{t} + A_{n} + \Gamma _{n} {\text{MY}}_{{t + 1}}^{n} )E_{t} [\exp ( - \Lambda _{t}^{\prime } \nu _{{t + 1}} + B_{n}^{\prime } (\mu + \Phi X_{t} + \nu _{{t + 1}} ))] \hfill \\ = \exp [ - \delta _{0} - \delta _{1}^{\prime } X_{t} - \delta _{2} MY_{t} - \frac{1}{2}\Lambda _{t}^{\prime } \Omega \Lambda _{t} + A_{n} + \Gamma _{n} {\text{MY}}_{{t + 1}}^{n} + B_{n}^{\prime } (\mu + \Phi X_{t} )]E_{t} [\exp ( - \Lambda _{t}^{\prime } \nu _{{t + 1}} + B_{n}^{\prime } \nu _{{t + 1}} )] \hfill \\ = \exp [ - \delta _{0} - \delta _{1}^{\prime } X_{t} - \frac{1}{2}\Lambda _{t}^{\prime } \Omega \Lambda _{t} + A_{n} - \delta _{2} {\text{MY}}_{t} + B_{n}^{\prime } (\mu + \Phi X_{t} ) + \Gamma _{n} {\text{MY}}_{{t + 1}}^{n} ]\exp \{ E_{t} [( - \Lambda _{t}^{\prime } + B_{n}^{\prime } )\nu _{{t + 1}} ] + \frac{1}{2}var[( - \Lambda _{t}^{\prime } + B_{n}^{\prime } )\nu _{{t + 1}} ]\} \hfill \\ = \exp [ - \delta _{0} - \delta _{1}^{\prime } X_{t} - \frac{1}{2}\Lambda _{t}^{\prime } \Omega \Lambda _{t} + A_{n} + B_{n}^{\prime } (\mu + \Phi X_{t} ) + \left[ { - \delta _{2} ,\gamma _{0}^{n} {\text{, }}\gamma _{1}^{n} \cdots ,\gamma _{{n - 1}}^{n} } \right]{\text{MY}}_{t}^{{n + 1}} ]\exp \{ \frac{1}{2}var[( - \Lambda _{t}^{\prime } + B_{n}^{\prime } )\nu _{{t + 1}} ]\} \hfill \\ \end{gathered}$$

To simplify the notation, we define \([-\delta _{2},\Gamma _{n} ]\equiv \left[ -\delta _{2},\gamma _{0}^{n}\text {, }\gamma _{1}^{n}\cdots ,\gamma _{n-1}^{n}\right]\)

$$\begin{aligned} = & \exp \left\{ { - \delta _{0} - \delta _{1}^{\prime } X_{t} - \frac{1}{2}\Lambda _{t}^{\prime } \Omega \Lambda _{t} + A_{n} + B_{n}^{\prime } (\mu + \Phi X_{t} ) + [ - \delta _{2} ,\Gamma _{n} ]{\text{MY}}_{t}^{{n + 1}} } \right\} \\ & \times \exp \left\{ {\frac{1}{2}E_{t} [( - \Lambda _{t}^{\prime } + B_{n}^{\prime } )\nu _{{t + 1}} \nu _{{t + 1}} \prime ( - \Lambda _{t} + B_{n} )]} \right\} \\ = & \exp \left\{ { - \delta _{0} - \delta _{1}^{\prime } X_{t} - \frac{1}{2}\Lambda _{t}^{\prime } \Omega \Lambda _{t} + A_{n} + B_{n}^{\prime } (\mu + \Phi X_{t} ) + [ - \delta _{2} ,\Gamma _{n} ]{\text{MY}}_{t}^{{n + 1}} } \right\} \\ & \times \exp \left\{ {\frac{1}{2}[\Lambda _{t}^{\prime } \Omega \Lambda _{t} - 2B_{n}^{\prime } \Omega \Lambda _{t} + B_{n}^{\prime } \Omega B_{n} )]} \right\} \\ = & \exp \left\{ { - \delta _{0} + A_{n} + B_{n}^{\prime } \mu + (B_{n}^{\prime } \Phi - \delta _{1}^{\prime } )X_{t} - B_{n}^{\prime } \Omega \Lambda _{t} + \frac{1}{2}B_{n}^{\prime } \Omega B_{n} + [ - \delta _{2} ,C_{n} ]MY_{t}^{{n + 1}} } \right\} \\ = & \exp \left\{ { - \delta _{0} + A_{n} + B_{n}^{\prime } \mu + (B_{n}^{\prime } \Phi - \delta _{1}^{\prime } )X_{t} - B_{n}^{\prime } \Omega (\lambda _{0} + \lambda _{1} X_{t} ) + \frac{1}{2}B_{n}^{\prime } \Omega B_{n} + [ - \delta _{2} ,\Gamma _{n} ]{\text{MY}}_{t}^{{n + 1}} } \right\} \\ = & \exp \left\{ {A_{1} + A_{n} + B_{n}^{\prime } (\mu - \Omega \lambda _{0} ) + \frac{1}{2}B_{n}^{\prime } \Omega B_{n} + (B_{n}^{\prime } \Phi - B_{n}^{\prime } \Omega \lambda _{1} + B_{1}^{\prime } )X_{t} + [ - \delta _{2} ,\Gamma _{n} ]{\text{MY}}_{t}^{{n + 1}} } \right\} \\ \end{aligned}$$

Then, we can find the coefficients following the difference equations:

$$\begin{gathered} A_{{n + 1}} = A_{1} + A_{n} + B_{n}^{\prime } (\mu - \Omega \lambda _{0} ) + \frac{1}{2}B_{n}^{\prime } \Omega B_{n} \hfill \\ B_{{n + 1}}^{\prime } = B_{n}^{\prime } \Phi - B_{n}^{\prime } \Omega \lambda _{1} + B_{1}^{\prime } \Gamma _{{n + 1}} = [ - \delta _{2} ,\Gamma _{n} ]. \hfill \\ \end{gathered}$$

Appendix B: Data Description

Demographic Variables

The U.S. annual population estimates series are collected from U.S. Census Bureau and the sample covers estimates from 1900–2050. Middle-aged to young ratio, MY\(_{t}\) is calculated as the ratio of the age group 40–49 to age group 20–29. Past MY\(_{t}\) projections for the period 1950–2013 are hand-collected from various past Census reports available at http://www.census.gov/prod/www/abs/p25.html. MY projections under different fertility rates are based on BoC’s 1975 population estimation and projections report.

Spot Rate

3-Month Treasury Bill rate is taken from Goyal and Welch (2008) extended collecting data from St. Louis FRED database.

Bond Yields

Bond yields are collected from Gurkaynak et al (2007) dataset, end of month data.

Core Inflation

Time series of core inflation are collected from St. Louis FRED database.

International Data

International bond yields are collected from Global Financial Data up to 2011. Benchmark bond yield is the 10-year constant maturity government bond yields. For Finland and Japan, shorter maturity bonds, 5-year and 7-year, respectively, are used, since a longer time series is available. International MY\(_{t}\) estimates for the period 1960–2008 are from World Bank Population estimates and projections from 2009 to 2050 are collected from International database (U.S. Census Bureau).

Macro Factors

Stationary output and inflation factors are constructed following the data appendix of Ludvigson and Ng (2009). Data series of Group 1 (output) and Group 7 (prices) are extended up to 2013Q4 using data from Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) and St. Louis FRED databases.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and Permissions

About this article

Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Favero, C.A., Gozluklu, A.E. & Yang, H. Demographics and the Behavior of Interest Rates. IMF Econ Rev 64, 732–776 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-016-0020-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-016-0020-2

JEL

  • E43
  • E44
  • J11