Abstract
Economics ignores persuasion in the economy. The economics of asymmetric “information” or common “knowledge” over the past 40 years speaks of costs and benefits but bypasses persuasion, “sweet talk.” Sweet talk accounts for a quarter of national income, and so is not mere “cheap talk.” Research should direct economics and the numerous other social sciences influenced by economics back towards human meaning in speech – meaning which has even in the most rigorously behaviorist experiments been shown to matter greatly to the outcome. Sweet talk is deeply unpredictable, which connects it to the troubled economics of entrepreneurship, of discovery, and of innovation. The massive innovation leading to the Great Enrichment of modern economic growth since 1800 is a leading case in point. Economic historians are beginning to find that material causes of the Great Enrichment do not work, and that changes in rhetoric do work, such as the Enlightenment and the Bourgeois Revaluation and above all Adam Smith’s “liberal plan of equality, liberty, and justice.” It is not, however, the new institutional economics, which is Samuelsonian economics redux. A new economic history emerges, using all the evidence for the scientific task: books as much as bonds, entrepreneurial courage and hope as much as managerial prudence and temperance.
Similar content being viewed by others
References
Akerlof, George, and Robert Shiller. 2009. Animal Spirits: How Human Psychology Drives the Economy, and Why It Matters for Global Capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press
Akerlof, George. 2006. “The Missing Motivation in Economics.” Manuscript of presidential address to the American Economic Association. http://www.aeaweb.org/annual_mtg_papers/2007/0106_1640_0101.pdf
Boettke, Peter J. 2012. Living Economics: Yesterday, Today, and Tomorrow. Oakland: The Independent Institute
Boudreaux, Donald J. 2012. Hypocrites & Half-Wits: A Daily Dose of Sanity from Cafe Hayek. Erie, PA: Free To Choose Press
Bowles, Samuel, and Herbert Gintis. 2011. A Cooperative Species: Human Sociality and Its Evolution. Princeton: Princeton University Press
Chamlee-Wright, Emily. 2010. The Cultural and Political Economy of Recovery: Social Learning in a Post-Disaster Environment. New York: Routledge
Friedman, Benjamin M. 2005. The Moral Consequences of Economic Growth. New York: Knopf
Gintis, Herbert. 2009. The Bounds of Reason: Game Theory and the Unification of the Behavioral Sciences. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
Clifford Geertz, Hildred Geertz, and Lawrence Rosen. 1979. Meaning and Order in Moroccan Society: Three Essays in Cultural Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Goldstone, Jack A. 2009. Why Europe? The Rise of the West in World History, 1500–1850. New York: McGraw-Hill
Greif, Avner. 2006. Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Grotius (Hugo de Groot). 1625. De jure belli ac pacis (On the Law of War and Peace). Paris, 1625 (2nd ed. Amsterdam 1631). Trans. as The Rights of War and Peace, ed. Richard Tuck. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 2005
Hayek, Friedrich. 1945. The Use of Knowledge in Society. American Economic Review, 35(Sept): 519–530
Hobbes, Thomas. 1651. Leviathan. London: J. M. Dent, 1914
Iannaccone, Laurence, and William S. Bainbridge. 2010. Economics of Religion, in The Routledge Companion to the Study of Religion, Second Edition, edited by John Hinnells. Oxford and New York: Routledge, 461–475
Israel, Jonathan I. 2006. Enlightenment Contested: Philosophy, Modernity, and the Emancipation of Man 1670-1752. New York: Oxford University Press
Jacob, Margaret C. 1997. Scientific Culture and the Making of the Industrial West. New York: Oxford University Press
_________________ 2014. The First Knowledge Economy: Human Capital and the European Economy, 1750–1850. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Jones, Eric L. 1988. Growth Recurring: Economic Change in World History. New York: Oxford University Press
_________________ 2010. Locating the Industrial Revolution: Inducement and Response. London: World Scientific
Keuhn, Aaron. 2008. Letter to the editor, Chicago Tribune, March 7
Kirzner, Israel M. 1979. “Knowing About Knowledge: A Subjectivist View of the Role of Information, in Kirzner, Perception, Opportunity, and Profit: Studies in the Theory of Entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 137–153
Klamer, Arjo, and Deirdre N. McCloskey. 1995. One Quarter of GDP is Persuasion. American Economic Review 85(May): 191–195
Klamer, Arjo. 2011. Cultural Entrepreneurship. Review of Austrian Economics 24:141–156
Klein, Daniel. 2012. Knowledge and Coordination: A Liberal Interpretation. Oxford: Oxford University Press
Lachmann, Ludwig. 1977. Capital, Expectations and the Market Process. Kansas City: Sheed Andrews and McMeel
Macfarlane, Alan. 1987. The Culture of Capitalism. Oxford: Basil Blackwell
_________________ 2000. The Riddle of the Modern World: Of Liberty, Wealth, and Equality. Basingstoke: Palgrave
Marschak, Jacob. 1968. Economics of Inquiring, Communicating, Deciding. American Economic Review, 58(May): 1–18
McCloskey, Deirdre N. 1989. Formalism in Economics, Rhetorically Speaking. Ricerche Economiche 43(Jan-June): 57–75
_________________ 1990. If You’re So Smart: The Narrative of Economic Expertise. Chicago: University of Chicago Press
_________________ 1991. Economic Science: A Search Through the Hyperspace of Assumptions? Methodus 3 (1 June): 6–16
_________________ 1994. Knowledge and Persuasion in Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
_________________ 2006. The Bourgeois Virtues: Ethics for an Age of Commerce. Chicago: University of Chicago Press
_________________ 2007. A Solution to the Alleged Inconsistency in the Neoclassical Theory of Markets: Reply to Guerrien’s Reply. Post-Autistic Economics Review May
_________________ 2010. Bourgeois Dignity: Why Economics Can’t Explain the Modern World. Chicago: University of Chicago Press
_________________ 2015a. Max U versus Humanomics: A Critique of Neo-Institutionalism. Journal of Institutional Economics Spring 2015: 1–27
_________________ 2015b. “The Humanities are Scientific: A Reply to the Defenses of Economic Neo-Institutionalism” (by Grief, Mokyr, Langois, Lawson, and Tomassini). Journal of Institutional Economics Fall 2015
_________________ 2016. Bourgeois Equality: How Ideas, Not Capital or Institutions, Enriched the World. Chicago: University of Chicago Press
Mehta, Judith. 1993. Meaning in the Context of Bargaining Games—Narratives in Opposition, in Economics and Language, edited by Willie Henderson, W., T. Dudley-Evans, and Roger Backhouse. London: Routledge, 85–99
Mokyr, Joel. 2010. The Enlightened Economy: An Economic History of Britain 1700–1850. London: Penguin Press; New Haven: Yale University Press
Mokyr, Joel. 2016. Culture of Growth: Origins of the Modern Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press
Nelson, Robert H. 1991. Reaching for Heaven on Earth: The Theological Meaning of Economics. Lanham, Maryland: Rowman & Littlefield
Nelson, Robert H. 2001. Economics as Religion: From Samuelson to Chicago and Beyond. University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press
Nelson, Robert H. 2010. The New Holy Wars: Economic Religion versus Environmental Religion in Contemporary America. University Park, PA: Penn State Press
North, Douglass C. 1991. Institutions. Journal of Economic Perspectives 5(1, Winter): 97–112
Novick, Peter. 1988. That Noble Dream: The ‘Objectivity Question’ and the American Historical Profession. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Ostrom, Eleanor, Roy Gardner, and J. Walker. 1994. Rules, Games, and Common-pool Resources. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press
Posner, Richard. 1988. Law and Literature: A Misunderstood Relation. Cambridge: Harvard University Press
Rubinstein, Ariel. 2000. Economics and Language: Five Essays. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1946. “Capitalism.” Encyclopædia Britannica. New York: Encyclopædia Britannica
Skinner, Quentin. 1998. Liberty before Liberalism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Smith, Adam. 1759 (1790). The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Glasgow ed. Edited by D. D. Raphael and A. L. Macfie. Reprinted Indianapolis: Liberty Classics, 1976, 1982
_________________ 1762–63/1766. Lectures on Jurisprudence, edited by R. L. Meek, D. D. Raphael, and P. G. Stein. Glasgow Edition. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1978/1982
_________________ 1776. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Vol. 1. Glasgow ed. Edited by Campbell, Skinner, and Todd. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Reprinted Indianapolis: Liberty Classics, 1976
Smith, Vernon. 2007. Rationality in Economics: Constructivist and Ecological Forms. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Stigler, George J. 1961. The Economics of Information. Journal of Political Economy 69 (June): 213–225. Reprinted pp. 171-190 in Stigler, The Organization of Industry. Homewood. IL: Irwin, 1968
Storr, Virgil H. 2013. Understanding the Culture of Markets. New York: Routledge
Acknowledgements
A version of part of the present paper was presented at a panel at the AEA meetings in San Diego, January 6, 2013 organized Orley Ashenfelter and Angus Deaton; and then at the February, 2016 meetings of the Eastern Economic Association organized by the International Adam Smith Society. I thank for their comments the audience, the organizers, and the panelists (Kenneth Arrow and Vernon Smith; at one meeting; Jeffrey Young, Sandra Peart, David Levy, and Amos Witztum). The ending comes amended from an essay I wrote last year for the Journal of Institutional Economics [McCloskey 2015a].
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
McCloskey, D.N. “Adam Smith did Humanomics: So Should We”. Eastern Econ J 42, 503–513 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41302-016-0007-8
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41302-016-0007-8