Skip to main content
Log in

Adjusted repeated myopic use of the inverse elasticity pricing rule

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

It has been shown that repeated myopic use of inverse elasticity pricing rule converges on the profit maximizing price only if demand is sufficiently convex, and that it will never converge for linear or strictly concave demands (Fjell and Pal 2019). By myopic, we mean ignoring that elasticity and marginal cost may vary with output and price. We explore a price adjustment process, where at each stage the new price is a convex combination of the current price and the myopic price that is dictated by the inverse elasticity pricing rule. We show that as long as sufficient weight is placed on the current price, the price sequence converges on the profit maximizing price for all demands. The precise range of potential convex combinations for convergence are determined; both for the traditional (multiplicative) version of the inverse elasticity pricing rule, as well as for the unfamiliar additive version. A comparison of the two shows that the latter appears superior in the sense that it converges for a larger range of convex combinations, and that it seems simpler and more intuitive in its expression.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The additive version can also be expressed in terms of slope of the demand function and quantity as follows: \(p^{*}=c-\frac{q\left( p^{*}\right) }{q^{\prime }\left( p^{*}\right) }\).

  2. It is even clearer if we refer to elasticity as the a positive value (which is quite common) with a plus sign in front of the last term.

  3. Ray and Gramlich (2016) argue that the local slope of demand can be estimated through minute changes in price. Given a local estimate of slope, one has also identified local elasticity.

References

  • Baumol, W.J., and R.E. Quandt. 1964. Rules of thumb and optimally imperfect decisions. The American economic review 54 (2): 23–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besanko, D., and R.R. Braeutigam. 2002. Microeconomics: An integrated approach. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besanko, D., and R. Braeutigam. 2020. Microeconomics. New York: Wiley Global Education.

    Google Scholar 

  • Browning, E.K., and M.A. Zupan. 2002. Microeconomics: Theory and applications, 7th ed. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiang, A.C. 1984. Fundamental methods of mathematical economics. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dranove, D., D. Besanko, M. Shanley, and S. Schaefer. 2017. Economics of strategy. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fjell, K. 2003. Elasticity based pricing rules: A cautionary note. Applied Economics Letters 10 (12): 787–791.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fjell, K., and D. Pal. 2019. On repeated myopic use of the inverse elasticity pricing rule. Economics Letters 175: 12–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, M. 2009. The elasticity pricing rule for two-sided markets: A note. Review of Network Economics 8 (3): 1–8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laitinen, E.K. 2009. From complexities to the rules of thumb: Towards optimization in pricing decisions. International Journal of Applied Management Science 1 (4): 340–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mandel, A., and H. Gintis. 2016. Decentralized pricing and the strategic stability of Walrasian general equilibrium. Journal of Mathematical Economics 63: 84–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. 1994. Applied microeconomics. New York: WW Norton and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Monroe, K.B. 2002. Pricing: Making profitable decisions. New York: McGraw-Hill/Irwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Monroe, K.B., and J.L. Cox. 2001. Pricing practices that endanger profits. Marketing Management 10 (3): 42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nicholson, W., and C. Snyder. 1985. Microeconomic theory: Basic principles and extensions. New York: Dryden Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pindyck, R.S., and D.L. Rubinfeld. 2005. Microeconomics, 6th ed. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ray, K., and J. Gramlich. 2016. Reconciling full-cost and marginal-cost pricing. Journal of Management Accounting Research 28 (1): 27–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saari, D.G. 1985. Iterative price mechanisms. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 53: 1117–1131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H., D. Zatta, and M. Fassnacht. 1989. Price management. New York: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kenneth Fjell.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Fjell, K., Pal, D. Adjusted repeated myopic use of the inverse elasticity pricing rule. J Revenue Pricing Manag 20, 559–565 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41272-020-00272-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41272-020-00272-0

Keywords

Navigation