Skip to main content
Log in

Raising rivals’ costs or improving efficiency? An exploratory study of managers’ views on backward integration in the grocery market

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Aims and scope

Abstract

Large retail grocery chains’ backward integration into distribution, procurement and production is controversial, and has received a lot of attention by both policy makers and market players. If a large retail chain for instance takes over scale intensive distribution activities to its own outlets from some suppliers, direct distribution from these suppliers to other retail chains might become more expensive (and could even initiate costly industry-wide backward integration). An interesting question is thus whether large retailers undertake backward integration mainly for efficiency reasons or whether they do so in order to gain a competitive advantage through raising the costs of the smaller rivals. Theory and econometric analyses are inconclusive. The current study uses semi-structured interviews to investigate managers’ views on this issue, and does not formally test different theories. However, the results clearly indicate that large retail chains gain a competitive advantage if they choose to backward integrate, but that their main motivation for choosing this strategy is to increase channel efficiency.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Interestingly, a pull factor behind A&P’s backward integration seems to be that the company wanted to sell breakfast food products at a lower price than the one set by the dominant producer, Cream of Wheat (see https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/The_Great_Atlantic_%26_Pacific_Tea_Company). Cream of Wheat’s use of resale price maintenance (RPM) was approved by District Court Judge Charles Hough, and contrasts sharply with the U.S. Supreme Court’s decision in the Dr. Miles v Park & Sons case.

  2. Hviid and Olczak (2016) analyse how raising fixed costs may be used to exclude rivals.

  3. Source market shares: AC Nielsen, 2014.

  4. This is an effect analogous to what we find in markets with positive network effects (see Farrell and Saloner 1992, and Katz and Shapiro 1985, among others).

  5. Source market shares: AC Nielsen, 2014, 2017.

  6. During the last year, it has been a huge attention towards that REMA has a slight reduction in their market shares the first two quarters of 2017. At first glance, this also seems consistent with the size effects since their rivals NG and COOP have increased their market shares. However, we want to be careful with such an interpretation, since the loss of REMA in 2017 may also be explained by huge marketing campaigns that consumers have disliked.

References

  • Basker, E. 2007. The causes and consequences of Wal-Mart’s growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives 21 (3): 177–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom, P.N., G.T. Gundlach, and J.P. Cannon. 2000. Slotting allowances and fees: Schools of thought and the views of practicing managers. Journal of Marketing 64 (2): 92–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cachon, G.P., and P.T. Harker. 2002. Competition and outsourcing with scale economies. Management Science 48 (10): 1314–1333.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Competition Commission. 2008. The supply of groceries in the UK market investigation, 30 April.

  • The Economist. 2017. An industry shudders as Amazon buys Whole Foods for $13.7 bn, June 16 2017.

  • Ellickson, P.B. 2007. Does Sutton apply to supermarkets? Rand Journal of Economics 38 (1): 43–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellickson, P.B. 2016. The evolution of the supermarket industry: From A&P to Walmart. In Handbook on the economics of retailing and distribution, ed. E. Basker. Cambridge: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Farrell, J., and G. Saloner. 1992. Converters, compatibility, and the control of interfaces. Journal of Industrial Economics 40 (1): 9–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foros, Ø., and H.J. Kind. 2017. Upstream partnerships among competitors when size matters, CESifo Working Paper No. 6512, June 2017.

  • Holmes, T.J. 2001. Bar codes lead to frequent deliveries and superstores. Rand Journal of Economics 32 (4): 708–725.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmes, T.J. 2011. The diffusion of Wal-Mart and economies of density. Econometrica 79 (1): 253–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling, H. 1929. Stability in competition. Economic Journal 39: 41–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hviid, M., and M. Olczak. 2016. Raising rivals’ fixed costs. International Journal of the Economics of Business 23 (1): 19–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inderst, R., and T. Valletti. 2011. Buyer power and the “Waterbed effect”. The Journal of Industrial Economics 59 (1): 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz, M. 1987. The welfare effects of third-degree price discrimination in intermediate good markets. American Economic Review 77 (1): 154–167.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz, M., and C. Shapiro. 1985. Network externalities, competition, and compatibility. American Economic Review 75 (3): 424–440.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCracken, G. The Long Interview. Qualitative Research Methods Series 13, A Sage University Paper. Thousand Oaks,. CA: Sage.

  • Oslo Economics. 2017. Etableringsbarrierer i dagligvaremarkedet [Access barriers in the (Norwegian) grocery market]. Written for the Norwegian Ministry of Trade, Industry and Fisheries.

  • Rubinfeld, D.L., and M. Gal. 2017. Access barriers to big data. Arizona Law Review 59 (2): 339–381.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salop, S.C., and D.T. Scheffman. 1983. Raising rivals’ costs. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 73: 267–271.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saunders, M., P. Lewis, and A. Thornhill. 2016. Research methods for business Students, 7th ed. Harlow: Pearson Education Limited.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, H. 2016. The economics of retailer-supplier pricing relationships: Theory and evidence. In Handbook on the economics of retailing and distribution, ed. E. Basker. Cambridge: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to the interview participants, and to Nina Skage for helping us with contact information. Solfrid Mykland, Inger G. Stensaker, and Christine B. Meyer have provided useful comments and suggestions. Finally, we thank the Norwegian Competition Authority for financial support.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Øystein Foros.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 2

From Eqs. (1) to (5) in “Backward integration might be profitable even if own costs increase” section we find:

$$\pi_{1}^{\text{B}} - \pi_{1}^{\text{N}} = \beta \left( { - \frac{1}{4} + \Delta_{1} \left( {\frac{1}{6}\frac{1}{3 - 2\beta } + \frac{1}{36}\Delta_{1} \frac{15 - 8\beta }{{t(3 - 2\beta )^{2} }}} \right)} \right)$$
(6)

First, note that if there is no size effect, β = 0, firm 1 is indifferent between backward integration or not. In this case, if firm 1 chooses backward integration, this gives rise to a competitive advantage over firm 2 as long as Δ1 > 0. However, under the spatial demand set-up, firm 2 would reduce its price accordingly to nullify the profit effect. Obviously, this neutrality result does not survive under alternative demand specification, but it allows us to scrutinize the specific properties of the size effects of the present model.

Therefore, let us concentrate on β > 0. We now observe that (6) is negative if Δ1 = 0. Furthermore, we directly observe (6) is increasing in Δ1 as long as β > 0. The upper bound of Δ1 is given by the value that forecloses firm 2 from the market; i.e. Δ1 = 3 − 2β. Inserting for Δ1 = 3 − 2β into (6) we have

$$(\pi_{1}^{\text{B}} - \pi_{1}^{\text{N}} )_{{\Delta_{1} = 3 - 2\beta }} = \frac{\beta }{9}(3 - 2\beta ) > 0.$$

Consequently, there exists a critical value of Δ1, such that if \(\Delta_{1} \ge \Delta_{1}^{\text{crit}} > 0,\) then \(\pi_{1}^{\text{B}} - \pi_{1}^{\text{N}} \ge 0,\) and firm 1 prefers backward integration. QED.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bernes, H.S., Flo, I.M., Foros, Ø. et al. Raising rivals’ costs or improving efficiency? An exploratory study of managers’ views on backward integration in the grocery market. J Revenue Pricing Manag 18, 65–75 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41272-017-0136-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41272-017-0136-7

Keywords

Navigation