Skip to main content
Log in

Bank procyclicality, business cycles and capital requirements

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Banking Regulation Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The present work seeks to rationalize the procyclical movements of credit, deposits and bank leverage, basic elements that justify the existence of macroprudential policies, and the effects of capital requirements on the business cycle and financial stability. For this purpose, we use an extension of the theoretical framework of Bernanke et al. [Handbook of Macroeconomics, Elsevier, New York, pp 1341–1393, 1999], which includes the presence of banks through the existence of a second asymmetry between banks and depositors. This extension allows us to understand the role of bank capital on the business cycle and, in this way, how credit channels and financial stability are affected by the inclusion of capital requirements as has been proposed in the Basel III Agreement. The results suggest that capital requirements act as a significant financial accelerator in the presence of productivity and monetary shocks. In addition, during expansions, banking capital regulation helps not only the real part of the economy perform better but also the financial part, through lesser leverage for entrepreneurs and banks. Our results also suggest that an asymmetric regulation constraint throughout the business cycle is preferable to a fixed one.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Source: Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED) and Bloomberg

Fig. 2

Source: Author’s calculations

Fig. 3

Source: Author’s calculations

Fig. 4

Source: Author’s calculations

Fig. 5

Source: FRED, Bloomberg and author’s calculations

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Although there is only a representative family, the existence of infinite identical banks implies that family provides the same quantity of deposits to each bank.

  2. See appendix 1 for more details.

  3. See “Appendix 2” for more details.

References

  1. Bernanke, B., M. Gertler, and S. Gilchrist. 1999. The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business Cycle Framework. In Handbook of Macroeconomics, ed. J.B. Taylor and M. Woodford, 1341–1393. New York: Elsevier.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  2. Borio, C. (2012). The Financial Cycle and Macroeconomics: What Have we Learn? Monetary and Economic Department. Bank for International Settlements, Working Papers No. 395.

  3. Athanasoglou, P., I. Daniilidis, and Manthos D. Delis. 2014. Bank Procyclicality and Output: Issues and Policies. Journal of Economics and Business. 72: 58–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Gersbach, H., and J.C. Rochet. 2017. Capital Regulation and Credit Fluctuations. Journal of Monetary Economics 10: 1–12. https://doi.org/10.2016/jmoneco.2017.05.008.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Zhu, H. 2008. Capital Regulation and Banks’ Financial Decisions. International Journal of Central Banking 4 (1): 165–211.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Zhang, L. (2009). Bank Capital Regulation, the Lending Channel and Business Cycles. Number 33. Discussion Paper Series 1: Economic Studies.

  7. Dib, A, (2010). Banks, Credit Market Frictions, and Business Cycles. Bank of Canada. Working Paper Series 2010-24.

  8. Covas, F., and S. Fujita. 2010. Procyclicality of Capital Requirements in a General Equilibrium Model of Liquidity Dependence. International Journal of Central Banking 6 (4): 137–173.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Meh, C.A., and K. Moran. 2010. The Role of Bank Capital in the Propagation of Shocks. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34 (3): 555–576.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Aliaga-Díaz, R., and M.P. Olivero. 2012. Do Bank Capital Requirements Amplify Business Cycles? Bridging the Gap Between Theory and Empirics. Journal of Macroeconomic Dynamics 16 (03): 358–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Holmstrom, B., and J. Tirole. 1998. Private and Public Supply of Liquidity. Journal of Political Economy 106 (1): 1–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Curdia, V., and Woodford, M. (2009). Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Monetary and Economic Department. Bank for International Settlements, Working Paper, No 278.

  13. Christiano, L., Motto, R., and Rostango M. (2010). Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. European Central Bank, Working Paper Series, No. 1192.

  14. Dellas, H., Diba, B., and Loisel, O. (2010). Financial Shocks and Optimal Policy. Bank of France, Working Paper, No 277.

  15. Gertler, M., and P. Karadi. 2011. A Model of Unconventional Monetary Policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 58 (1): 17–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Jermann, U., and V. Quadrini. 2012. Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Shocks. The American Economic Review 102 (1): 238–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Bernanke, B., and M. Gertler. 1989. Agency Costs, Net Worth, and Business Fluctuations. The American Economic Review 79 (1): 14–31.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Carlstrom, C.T., and T.S. Fuerst. 1997. Agency Costs, Net Worth, and Business Fluctuations: A Computable General Equilibrium Analysis. The American Economic Review 87 (5): 893–910.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Kiyotaki, N., and J. Moore. 1997. Credit Cycles. Journal of Political Economy 105 (2): 211–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Meeks, R. 2017. Capital Regulation and The Macroeconomy: Empirical Evidence and Macroprudential Policy. European Economic Review. 95: 125–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Dell’Ariccia, M. G., Marquez, M. R., and Laeven, M. L. (2010). Monetary Policy, Leverage, and Bank Risk-Taking. Number 10-276. International Monetary Fund.

  22. Borio, C., and H. Zhu. 2012. Capital Regulation, Risk-Taking and Monetary Policy: A Missing Link in the Transmission Mechanism? Journal of Financial Stability 8: 236–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Angeloni, I., and E. Faia. 2013. Capital Regulation and Monetary Policy with Fragile Banks. Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (3): 311–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Kiley, M., and Jae Sim. 2017. Optimal Monetary and Macroprudential Policies: Gains and Pitfalls in a Model of Financial Intermediation. Journal of Macroeconomics 54: 232–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Clancy, D., and R. Merola. 2017. Countercyclical Capital Rules for Small Open Economies. Journal of Macroeconomics 54: 332–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Calvo, G.A. 1983. Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework. Journal of Monetary Economics 12 (1): 383–398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Gale, D., and M. Hellwig. 1985. Incentive-Compatible Debt Contracts: The One-Period Problem. The Review of Economic Studies 52 (4): 647–663.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Collard, F, Dellas, H., Diba, B. (N.D.). A Suite of Models for Dynare. Description of Models. Mimeo.

  29. Badarau, C., and A. Popescu. 2014. Monetary Policy and Credit Cycles: A DSGE Analysis. Economic Modelling 42: 301–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Hirakata, N., N. Sudo, and K. Ueda. 2015. Do Banking Shocks Matter for the US Economy? Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 35 (1): 2042–2063.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Authors would like to acknowledge at the participants of following conferences for their comments and contributions: XXI Applied Economics Meeting, University of Alcalá, Madrid – Spain; XXXVI Meeting of Economists of Peru and Central Reserve Bank of Peru, Lima – Peru; XXIII Latin American and Caribbean Economic Association Conference (LACEA); Guayaquil-Ecuador.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alejandro Torres-García.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Evolution of the entrepreneurial net worth and bank capital

To derive the evolution of entrepreneurial net worth, it is important to note that in the optimum the incentive participations constraints of bankers and depositors should be binding. It implies:

$$ \left[ {1 - F\left( {\bar{\omega }} \right)} \right]\bar{\omega }R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} = R_{t}^{p} M_{t + 1} + \left( {1 - \mu } \right)\left[ {1 - F\left( {\omega^{*} } \right)} \right]\omega^{*} R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - \left( {1 - \mu } \right)\mathop \int \limits_{{\omega^{*} }}^{{\bar{\omega }}} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} $$
(19)

Now, the depositors expected profits should be equal at their oportunity cost:

$$ \left( {1 - \mu } \right)\left[ {1 - F\left( {\omega^{*} } \right)} \right]\omega^{*} R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} = R_{t}^{p} \left( {Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - N_{t} - M_{t} } \right) - \left( {1 - \gamma } \right)\left( {1 - \mu } \right)\mathop \int \limits_{0}^{{\omega^{*} }} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} $$
(20)

Using both equations we find that:

$$ \left[ {1 - F\left( {\bar{\omega }} \right)} \right]\bar{\omega }R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} = R_{t}^{p} \left( {Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - N_{t} } \right) - \left[ {\left( {1 - \gamma } \right)\mathop \int \limits_{0}^{{\bar{\omega }}} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - \gamma \left( {1 - \mu } \right)\mathop \int \limits_{0}^{{\omega^{*} }} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} } \right] $$
(21)

Replacing this expression in the entrepreneur expected profits, we can writte:

$$ \varPi^{e} = R_{t + 1}^{k} Q_{t} K_{t + 1} - R_{t}^{p} \left( {Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - N_{t} } \right) - \mu \mathop \int \limits_{{\omega^{*} }}^{{\bar{\omega }}} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - \left[ {\gamma + \mu \left( {1 - \gamma } \right)} \right]\mathop \int \limits_{0}^{{\omega^{*} }} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} $$

Finally, the net worth entrepreneurial profits can be written as:

$$ V_{t} = R_{t + 1}^{k} Q_{t} K_{t + 1} - \left\{ {R_{t}^{p} + \frac{{\left[ {\mu \mathop \int \nolimits_{{\omega^{*} }}^{{\bar{\omega }}} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega - \left( {\gamma + \mu \left( {1 - \gamma } \right)} \right)\mathop \int \nolimits_{0}^{{\omega^{*} }} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega } \right]R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} }}{{Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - N_{t} }}} \right\}\left( {Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - N_{t} } \right) $$

where \( \left( {\frac{{\left[ {\mu \mathop \int \nolimits_{{\omega^{*} }}^{{\bar{\omega }}} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega - \left( {\gamma + \mu \left( {1 - \gamma } \right)} \right)\mathop \int \nolimits_{0}^{{\omega^{*} }} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega } \right]R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} }}{{Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - N_{t} }}} \right) \) is the financial premium that bankers charge to entrepreneurs due the existence of asymetric information.

In a similar way, it is possible to derive the expression for the evolution of bank capital. To do that, we start with the banker expected profits function:

$$ \left[ {1 - F\left( {\bar{\omega }} \right)} \right]\bar{\omega }R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} + \left( {1 - \mu } \right)\mathop \int \limits_{{\omega^{*} }}^{{\bar{\omega }}} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - \left( {1 - \mu } \right)\left[ {1 - F\left( {\omega^{*} } \right)} \right]\omega^{*} R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} $$
(22)

Using the depositors expected profits binding, we can writte:

$$ \left[ {1 - F\left( {\bar{\omega }} \right)} \right]\bar{\omega }R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} + \left( {1 - \mu } \right)\mathop \int \limits_{{\omega^{*} }}^{{\bar{\omega }}} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} + \left( {1 - \gamma } \right)\left( {1 - \mu } \right)\mathop \int \limits_{0}^{{\omega^{*} }} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - R_{t}^{p} \left( {Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - N_{t} - M_{t} } \right) $$

Rewritting, we obtain the evolution of bank wealth as:

$$ V_{t}^{b} = \left\{ {\left[ {1 - F\left( {\bar{\omega }} \right)} \right]\bar{\omega } + \left( {1 - \mu } \right)\mathop \int \limits_{0}^{{\bar{\omega }}} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega } \right\}R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - \left\{ {R_{t}^{p} + \frac{{\gamma \left( {1 - \mu } \right)\mathop \int \nolimits_{0}^{{\omega^{*} }} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} }}{{Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - N_{t} - M_{t} }}} \right\}\left( {Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - N_{t} - M_{t} } \right) $$
(23)

where (\( \frac{{\gamma \left( {1 - \mu } \right)\mathop \int \nolimits_{0}^{{\omega^{*} }} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} }}{{Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - N_{t} - M_{t} }} \) is the financial premium that depositors charge at bankers due the asymetric information problem.

Appendix 2: Model equations system

Aggregate demand:

$$ Y_{t} = C_{t} + C_{t}^{e} + C_{t}^{b} + I_{t} + \mu \mathop \int \limits_{{\omega^{*} }}^{{\bar{\omega }}} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega + \left[ {\gamma + \mu \left( {1 - \gamma } \right)} \right]\mathop \int \limits_{0}^{{\omega^{*} }} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega $$
(24)
$$ \frac{1}{{C_{t} }} = \beta {\mathbb{E}}_{t} \left[ {\frac{{R_{t + 1}^{d} }}{{C_{t + 1} }}} \right] $$
(25)
$$ C_{t}^{e} = \left( {1 - \gamma^{e} } \right)V_{t} $$
(26)
$$ C_{t}^{b} = \left( {1 - \gamma^{b} } \right)V_{t}^{b} $$
(27)
$$ {\mathbb{E}}_{t} \left( {R_{t + 1}^{k} } \right) = {\mathbb{E}}_{t} \left( {\frac{{1/X_{t + 1} \left( {\alpha Y_{t + 1} /K_{t + 1} } \right) + \left( {1 - \delta } \right)Q_{t + 1} }}{{Q_{t} }}} \right) $$
(28)
$$ {\mathbb{E}}_{t} \left( {\frac{{R_{t + 1}^{k} }}{{R_{t} }}} \right) = \frac{{n_{{\bar{\omega }}} \left( {\bar{\omega }_{t + 1} } \right)g_{{\omega^{ *} }} \left( {\omega_{t + 1}^{ *} ,\bar{\omega }_{t + 1} } \right)}}{{n\left( {\bar{\omega }_{t + 1} } \right)g_{{\bar{\omega }}} \left( {\omega_{t + 1}^{ *} ,\bar{\omega }_{t + 1} } \right)h_{{\omega^{ *} }} \left( {\omega_{t + 1}^{ *} } \right) - n_{{\bar{\omega }}} \left( {\bar{\omega }} \right)g\left( {\omega_{t + 1}^{ *} ,\bar{\omega }_{t + 1} } \right)h_{{\omega^{ *} }} \left( {\omega_{t + 1}^{ *} } \right) + n_{{\bar{\omega }}} \left( {\bar{\omega }_{t + 1} } \right)g_{{\omega^{ *} }} \left( {\omega_{t + 1}^{ *} ,\bar{\omega }_{t + 1} } \right)h\left( {\omega_{t + 1}^{ *} } \right)}} $$
(29)
$$ {\mathbb{E}}_{t} \left( {\frac{{R_{t + 1}^{k} }}{{R_{t} }}} \right) = \frac{{Q_{t} K_{t + 1} - M_{t + 1} - N_{t + 1} }}{{h_{{\omega^{ *} }} \left( {\omega_{t + 1}^{ *} } \right)Q_{t} K_{t + 1} }} $$
(30)
$$ \frac{{Q_{t} K_{t + 1} }}{{N_{t + 1} }} = {\mathbb{E}}_{t} \left( {\frac{{R_{t} }}{{R_{t + 1}^{k} }}} \right)\frac{{M_{t + 1} }}{{g\left( {\omega_{t + 1}^{ *} ,\bar{\omega }_{t + 1} } \right)N_{t} }} $$
(31)
$$ Q_{t} = \frac{1}{\theta }\left( {\frac{{I_{t} }}{{K_{t} }}} \right)^{{1 - \alpha_{1} }} $$
(32)

Aggregate supply:

$$ Y_{t} = A_{t} K_{t}^{\alpha } \left[ {H_{t}^{\varOmega } \left( {H_{t}^{e} } \right)^{{\varOmega_{1} }} \left( {H_{t}^{b} } \right)^{{1 - \varOmega - \varOmega_{1} }} } \right]^{1 - \alpha } $$
(33)
$$ \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\varOmega \frac{{Y_{t} }}{{H_{t} }} = X_{t} W_{t} $$
(34)
$$ \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\varOmega_{1} \frac{{Y_{t} }}{{H_{t}^{e} }} = X_{t} W_{t}^{e} $$
(35)
$$ \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)(1 - \varOmega - \varOmega_{1} ) \frac{{Y_{t} }}{{H_{t}^{b} }} = X_{t} W_{t}^{b} $$
(36)
$$ \frac{{W_{t} }}{{C_{t} }} = \xi \frac{1}{{1 - H_{t} }} $$
(37)

State variables evolution:

$$ K_{t + 1} = \theta I_{t}^{{\alpha_{1} }} K_{t}^{{1 - \alpha_{1} }} + \left( {1 - \delta } \right)K_{t} $$
(38)
$$ N_{t + 1} = \gamma^{e} V_{t} + W_{t}^{e} $$
(39)
$$ V_{t} = R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - \left\{ {R_{t}^{p} + \frac{{\left[ {\mu \mathop \int \nolimits_{{\omega^{*} }}^{{\bar{\omega }}} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega - \left( {\gamma + \mu \left( {1 - \gamma } \right)} \right)\mathop \int \nolimits_{0}^{{\omega^{*} }} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega } \right]R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} }}{{Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - N_{t} }}} \right\}\left( {Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - N_{t} } \right) $$
(40)
$$ M_{t + 1} = \gamma^{b} V_{t}^{b} + W_{t}^{b} $$
(41)
$$ V_{t}^{b} = \left\{ {\left[ {1 - F\left( {\bar{\omega }} \right)} \right]\bar{\omega } + \left( {1 - \mu } \right)\mathop \int \limits_{0}^{{\bar{\omega }}} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega } \right\}R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - \left\{ {R_{t}^{p} + \frac{{\gamma \left( {1 - \mu } \right)\mathop \int \nolimits_{0}^{{\omega^{*} }} \omega f\left( \omega \right)d\omega R_{t}^{k} Q_{t - 1} K_{t} }}{{Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - N_{t} - M_{t} }}} \right\}\left( {Q_{t - 1} K_{t} - N_{t} - M_{t} } \right) $$
(42)

Monetary policy and shocks:

$$ P_{t}^{N} = \frac{{\theta_{p} }}{{\theta_{p} - 1}}\varLambda_{t} P_{t}^{{1 + \theta_{p} }} s_{t} y_{t} + \beta \chi {\mathbb{E}}_{t} \left[ {\pi_{t + 1}^{{\theta_{p} }} P_{t + 1}^{N} } \right] $$
(43)
$$ P_{t}^{D} = \varLambda_{t} P_{t}^{{\theta_{p} }} y_{t} + \beta \chi {\mathbb{E}}_{t} \left[ {P_{t + 1}^{D} } \right] $$
(44)
$$ R_{t}^{n} = \rho_{0} R_{t - 1}^{n} + \theta^{\pi } \left( {\pi_{t} - \pi_{ss} } \right) + \theta^{y} \left( {y_{t} - y_{ss} } \right) + \varepsilon_{t} $$
(45)
$$ A_{t} = \rho_{A} A_{t - 1} + \varepsilon_{t}^{A} ;\quad \varepsilon_{t}^{A} \sim N\left( {0,\sigma_{A}^{2} } \right) $$
(46)
$$ \varepsilon_{t} = \rho_{\varepsilon } \varepsilon_{t - 1} + u_{t}^{\varepsilon } ;\quad u_{t}^{\varepsilon } \sim N\left( {0,\sigma_{\varepsilon }^{2} } \right) $$
(47)

Appendix 3: Calibration and steady state

See Table 3.

Table 3 Calibration non regulated models

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Torres-García, A., Ballesteros-Ruiz, C.A. & Villca-Condori, A. Bank procyclicality, business cycles and capital requirements. J Bank Regul 21, 152–169 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41261-019-00102-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41261-019-00102-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation