Flexible spending accounts (FSA) for healthcare expenses offer an attractive way for U.S. residents to avoid taxes. A recent Kaiser Family Foundation/Health Research and Educational Trust survey of 1,997 public and private employers finds that 73 per cent of large firms (200+ employees) and 20 per cent of small firms (3–199 employees) offered such accounts in 2007.Footnote 1

The advantage to the employee can be significant, although there is a financial risk. The advantage is that qualified expenses escape both state and federal income taxation and also all payroll taxes; the risk is that unused funds are forfeited to the employee's firm at the end of the period. Employers also avoid payroll taxes on employee elections.

FSA participation decisions are made concurrently with insurance plan choices each year during the firm's open enrolment period. Therefore, these decisions are made jointly, and with the same information. Because FSAs cover out-of-pocket costs, their availability should have predictable effects on insurance choices. Hamilton and MartonFootnote 2 and Jack et al. Footnote 3 both find evidence that FSA availability is associated with higher cost sharing in employer-sponsored plans.

SchlesingerFootnote 4 extends Mossin's theorem to “upper limit” insurance contracts in which the consumer purchases a fixed level of coverage. Consumers fully insure to the maximum loss if insurance is fairly priced. These are similar in some respects to FSAs. For FSAs, the “premium” per dollar of coverage is independent of risk, depending only on consumer's tax rate. Cardon and ShowalterFootnote 5 treat FSAs as a form of supplemental insurance. In that paper, individuals choose FSA participation levels in order to cover their out-of-pocket expenditures, treating the level of insurance coverage as given. Some of the implications for the interaction of insurance with FSA election levels are obvious; for example, if the the consumer has full insurance, the optimal FSA election amount is zero. However, this neglects the effect of FSA election amounts on optimal insurance coverage levels.

This paper extends these results by allowing for endogenous insurance choice. I show that the optimal level of insurance coverage is (weakly) lower with FSA participation if preferences exhibit decreasing or constant absolute risk aversion. In particular, I show when optimal FSA/insurance usage leads to higher deductibles even in cases where insurance is fairly priced. These results are then used to assess the effect of FSA coverage on the tax cost of health benefit exclusions. Finally, I consider the effect of employer subsidies.

Model

An individual with initial, pre-tax income I>0 and marginal tax rate t faces a loss x∈[0,L] where the maximum loss L<I(1−t). The continuous, non-degenerate probability density functionFootnote 6 for the loss is g(x) with a distribution function represented by G(x). I assume that G(x) is public information. The individual has preferences defined over consumption C, represented by a smooth, concave utility function U(C) with U′>0 and U″<0. The individual is eligible to participate in an FSA programme which allows the loss (or a portion of the loss) to be paid out of pre-tax dollars. The FSA election amount F must be chosen prior to the realisation of the loss. The portion of the loss in excess of F is not covered, and unused funds are forfeited.Footnote 7 The model assumes a two-stage choice. In the first stage, the consumer chooses an insurance contract and an FSA election amount. In the second, conditional on first stage choices and the realised health expenditure, the consumer chooses the withdrawal amount.

I assume that the alternative insurance contract is deductible insurance. Most insurance contracts include a deductible provision, and in typical use FSA funds will first be used to offset the deductible. FSAs work especially well with deductibles because the FSA provides first-dollar coverage of the loss up to the election amount, while a deductible contract covers nothing until the deductible level is reached. In contrast, FSAs do not complement a proportional insurance plan as easily.Footnote 8

Deductible insurance

In the absence of an FSA, the consumer chooses the deductible level, D⩾0, for an insurance contract that pays 100 per cent of losses in excess of the deductible. The premium is where λ is a proportional loading factor. Using integration by parts it can be shown that P′(D)=−(1+λ) (1−G(D)). Let the optimal deductible with no FSA be D 0. It is well known that the consumer will fully insure at D 0=0 if insurance is actuarially fair, and will partially insure if it is less than fair. The premium paid by the consumer for employer-provided insurance is excluded from taxable income. Given this implicit tax subsidy, what matters for insurance choice is the “fairness” as perceived by the consumer; that is, the consumer will fully insure if (1+λ) (1−t)⩽1.

Assume now that the consumer is offered an FSA together with deductible insurance coverage. The level of the deductible is now chosen together with the FSA election amount, F⩾0, prior to observing the loss. Once the loss x is realised, the consumer chooses a withdrawal, W, which must be less than or equal to the election amount and to total out-of-pocket expenditures. Therefore, given D, F and a realised loss x, consumption is C=(IP(D)−F)(1−t)+W−min{x, D}, subject to WF and W⩽min{x, D}. The optimisation problem is therefore:

subject to

and the non-negativity constraints F⩾0 and D⩾0.

To simplify the problem, note that once the loss x is revealed, the optimal withdrawal W * satisfies the following:

Further, FD because FSA balances in excess of the deductible will certainly be forfeited. Given these, we can define C 1=(IPF) (1−t) for x<F, C 2=(IP) (1−t)+tFx for Fx<D, and C 3=(IP) (1−t)+tFD for xD, implying C 1C 2>C 3. Expected utility is therefore

and the Lagrangian is:

The Kuhn-Tucker conditions are

where w.c.s. stands for with complementary slackness.

Proposition 1

  • The consumer's optimal deductible and FSA election amounts, D * and F *, are as follows:

    1. i)

      Given t>0 and λ>0, D *=F *>0 and G(D *)=λ/(1+λ) if and only if (1−t) (1+λ)⩽1.

    2. ii)

      Given t>0 and λ>0, D *>F *>0 if and only if (1−t) (1+λ)>1.

    3. iii)

      If t=0 and λ>0, then D *>F *=0.

    4. iv)

      If λ⩽0, then D *=F *=0.

Proof

  • See Appendix. □

Proposition 2

  • The consumer's optimal deductible is (weakly) higher with FSA participation if preferences exhibit constant or decreasing absolute risk aversion.

Proof

  • See Appendix. □

Summary

Comparative statics results are summarised in Figure 1. The upper panel shows the regions of full and partial deductible insurance without FSA. The curve labelled (1−t) (1+λ)=1 denotes combinations of t and λ for which insurance is actuarially fair, as perceived by the consumer. In the region on or above the curve we have (1−t) (1+λ)⩽1, and full insurance D 0=0 is optimal. Otherwise, partial insurance is chosen. With an FSA available, four regions in the lower panel are determined by values of (t, λ). If insurance is fair or better ((1−t) (1+λ)⩽1), λ>0 and t>0, then D *=F *>0, and coverage is full but mixed. In this case, the optimal deductible/election amount satisfies G(D *)=λ/(1+λ). Note that D * depends only on λ and the distribution of losses. For t>0, λ>0 and unfair insurance ((1−t) (1+λ)>1), D *>F*>0 and the consumer is only partially covered. For t=0 and λ>0, FSAs offer risk (of unused balances) and no reward; hence the optimal choice is partial deductible coverage and no FSA: D *>F*=0. This is shown by the dots on the horizontal axis. For any value of t, if λ⩽0, which might happen if the employer pays a portion of the insurance premium, then D *=F*=0.

Figure 1
figure 1

Comparative statics with and without FSAs.

When (1−t) (1+λ)⩽1 the consumer would, in the absence of an FSA, choose full deductible coverage, D 0=0. In contrast, a consumer with an FSA option will, given λ>0 and t>0, raise the deductible and compensate with some level of F*D *. The reason for this is that FSA “premium” per unit of coverage is constant at 1−t, while the insurance premium is non-linear in D. In particular, at D=0 we have −P′(0) (1−t)=(1+λ) (1−t)>1−t. Therefore, an increase in both D and F raises expected utility over full deductible coverage. In summary, if t>0 and λ>0 the optimal deductible is higher when an FSA is available, or D *>D 0.

Tax revenue costs of FSA participation

Federal and state law exempts certain health insurance premiums as well as FSA election amounts from taxes, which represents a substantial cost in reduced tax revenue. Sheils and HaughtFootnote 9 estimate a total state and federal tax cost for all health benefit exclusions of US$209.9 billion for 2004. The federal income tax exclusion for insurance alone is US$101 billion, or 53.6 per cent of the federal total. Reimbursement accounts, which include health reimbursement arrangements (HRAs) as well as FSAs, have an estimated federal tax cost of US$1.6 billion. In order to reduce these costs, the recently passed 2010 Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act places a US$2,500 limit (indexed for inflation) on FSA balances, beginning in 2013.Footnote 10

The marginal tax rate t that is relevant in determining a consumer's optimal choices F* and D * includes only taxes paid by the consumer. To determine the overall tax cost we must also include the portion of payroll taxes paid by the employer. Define τt as the sum of employer and consumer tax rates. Further, unused balances are forfeited to the employer and may be taxable depending on how the employer uses these funds.Footnote 11 Let the tax rate on forfeited funds be τ̂. The actual tax cost of FSAs is difficult to determine. If we take the deductible or other cost-sharing provisions of an insurance contract as exogenous, then we can estimate the tax cost as τF*. But if FSA usage leads to reduced insurance coverage, as shown above, then there will be an offsetting reduction in tax costs from lower insurance premium exclusions. The results from the previous section are used to assess the true tax cost of FSAs.

Deductible insurance with proportional loading

In case (i) from Proposition 1, t>0, λ>0 and (1−t) (1+λ)⩽1, implying D *=F*>0 and G(D *)=λ/(1+λ). In contrast, the optimal deductible without FSA is D 0=0. The change in tax revenue cost (TC) depends on the premium difference and the tax subsidy on the FSA balance:

Using G(D *)=λ/(1+λ) and simplifying yields

In this case, FSA participation raises the deductible to the same level as that of the FSA election amount, and the reduction in tax cost comes from the fact that insurance carries a positive loading factor. Despite the fact that insurance is better-than-fair because of the tax subsidy, FSA participation creates the incentive to switch coverage to FSA balances.

For case (ii), if t>0, λ>0 and (1−t) (1+λ)>1, then D *>F*>0. Here, there is a gap between F* and D *. The revenue cost of FSA is ΔTC=τ[P(D *)−P(D 0)]+τF*, or

Here the sign of ΔTC is ambiguous, but it is clear that ΔTCτF * since D *D 0 by Proposition 2. The first two terms will be negative if

Rearranging yields the condition

This is just the condition that the Mills Ratio (D)>D. Finally, for cases (iii) and (iv) there is no change in tax revenue, since the optimal FSA election amount is zero and, therefore, the deductible choice is unchanged.

Fixed loading

I have made the usual assumption that insurance loading is proportional to the premium. If, however, a source of the loading is fixed underwriting costs, then the marginal loading may be lower than the average. In the extreme case of purely fixed loading, P′(D)=−(1−G(D)), and there is no difference in tax cost at the margin.

Insurance options and employer subsidies

FSAs are offered through employers along with a menu of insurance options. Many employers offer generous insurance subsidies. Suppose the employer subsidises a fraction 0⩽s⩽1 of the insurance premium. Then (2) is replaced with

The condition for full insurance becomes (1−s) (1+λ) (1−t)⩽1 or (1+λ′) (1−t)⩽1, where λ′=λ(1−s)−s. The results of Proposition 1 hold if we replace λ with λ′. Then full deductible insurance and zero FSA is likely to be the common outcome, since λ′ will typically be negative.Footnote 12

Under current law, however, employers are permitted to make contributions to employee FSAs. A proportional match of employee contributions at the same rate s acts just as a subsidy and the resulting consumption equation is

Since the subsidies are equal for both insurance and FSA, it is easily seen that D *=F*=0 is not optimal, and the consumer will always choose mixed coverage.

If, instead, employers use a fixed insurance subsidy S and offer no FSA subsidy, consumption becomes

The subsidy will not affect the price of insurance at the margin because the consumer will always choose a deductible low enough to use all of the subsidy. Let S be the subsidy amount and let be the deductible level that solves P()=S. It is clear that the optimal deductible D *. Suppose that S is low, so that D *<. In this case, the subsidy is simply an increase in income and we have

Then the results of Proposition 1 hold qualitatively, with the only difference being an income that is higher by S. If the subsidy is high, then D *= and the subsidy determines the deductible. The optimal FSA level will then be chosen for that level of deductible, and the results in Cardon and Showalter5 hold.

Employer insurance pools and asymmetric information

The models above predict that employees with high levels of subsidies will choose full insurance, and that FSA election amounts would be zero. However, insurance markets are often characterised by asymmetric information in the form of adverse selection or moral hazard. The insurance options offered to employees reflect market responses to these information problems. With adverse selection, employers offer a menu of contracts of varying coverage levels (say, high and low deductibles) in order to separate high and low risk types.Footnote 13

With moral hazard, optimal contracts use cost-sharing in order to reduce over-consumption. In both these cases, employees cannot freely choose their levels of coverage, and full coverage is rarely offered. If D is fixed or chosen from a menu of options, then the consumer's problem is somewhat simplified and F might be thought of as simply a supplement to a fixed level of cost-sharing.

Alternatively, assume that insurance plan characteristics (cost-sharing and subsidy levels) are chosen along with the employee's income in order to attain a fixed level of compensation, as determined by a competitive labour market. Then FSA availability will likely lead to both a higher income and a higher deductible in anticipation of an offsetting FSA contribution by the employee. The firm's choice of income/benefits mix will reflect the underlying preferences of the employees, as given by the model above.

Conclusion

This paper has extended a simple model of FSA participation to examine the joint choice of insurance contracts and FSA election amounts. I have shown that FSAs do raise optimal deductible levels in some cases. This is most obvious in the case of deductible insurance, where the optimal deductible is positive even for better-than-fair insurance so long as tax rates and loading factors are positive. FSAs can be an attractive substitute for insurance when loading factors are high, but this is undermined by employer subsidies of insurance. FSA availability also has the potential to lower the tax cost of health subsidies, and estimates of FSA tax cost will be inflated if they do not account for the effect of FSA participation on insurance contract choices.