Skip to main content
Log in

Educational Quality Matters for Development: A Model of Trade, Inequality, and Endogenous Growth

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Eastern Economic Journal Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper addresses the dynamics of income inequality, both within and across countries, using an endogenous growth model with North–South trade and endogenous educational choice. The dynamics of income inequality is found to depend on the ability of workers to adapt to new technologies, captured by the quality of education. For developing countries with low quality of education, I find Southern trade liberalization leads to: (1) an overall decline in effective human capital; (2) an inverted U-shape transition of income inequality, where within-country inequality increases in the initial periods following a reduction in trade barriers; and (3) divergence in terms of average income in the short and long run. However, in cases where the South has a high quality of education, workers are better equipped to adapt to new technologies, and trade liberalization induces an U-shape dynamic transition of within-country income inequality, where income inequality can decline in the transition. This paper highlights the critical role the quality of education plays in explaining the variations in the observed dynamics of income inequality in developing countries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2
Figure 3
Figure 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Uses inequality data from the University of Texas Inequality Project (available at http://utip.gov.utexas.edu/data.html) and SEDLAC (CEDLAS and The World Bank).

  2. Data on GDP per capita is taken from Penn World Tables [Heston et al. 2006].

  3. However, this finding is challenged in Duryea and Szekely [2000] and Behrman et al. [2000] where they show inequality fell within Brazil, Mexico, Venezuela, Argentina, and Bolivia, and was constant in Chile and Costa Rica during the 1980s and 1990s.

  4. β-divergence in Barro and Sala-i-Martin [1992] terms.

  5. σ-divergence in Barro and Sala-i-Martin [1992]. See the “twin peaks” literature following Quah [1993].

  6. Introducing imperfect substitution between skilled and unskilled workers is possible, but the qualitative results would carry through and the analysis would be less transparent.

  7. Within industries, different quality grades are perfect substitutes, however, weighted by their respective grades.

  8. If this inequality does not hold, successful innovators charge monopoly prices and successful imitators engage in limit pricing strategies.

  9. Intermediate producers in the South only face competition from the North. Bertrand price competition drives prices down to marginal costs, thus fellow intermediate firms in the South have no incentive to devote resources to imitate a good that has already been imitated.

  10. The marginal cost of intermediate producers is equal to the price of the final good in that region. In the North, the price of the final good and therefore the marginal cost for intermediate firms in the North is unity, while the price of the Southern final good and marginal costs for Southern intermediate producers adjust to balance trade,

  11. For more details on learning-to-learn effects refer to Connolly [2003] and Connolly and Valderrama [2007].

  12. We assume trade is balanced at all times by the endogenous adjustment of the relative price of the Southern final good,

  13. A lump sum transfer of tariff revenues does not change the dynamics of income inequality.

  14. Code is available upon request.

  15. Trade liberalization of a lesser or greater magnitude induces the same qualitative results.

References

  • Acemoglu, D. 1998. Why Do New Technologies Complement Skills? Directed Technical Change and Wage Inequality. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(4): 1055–1089.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D. 2003. Patterns of Skill Premium. The Review of Economic Studies, 70(2): 199–230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion, P. 2002. Schumpeterian Growth Theory and the Dynamics of Income Inequality. Econometrica, 70(3): 855–882.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion, P., and P. Howitt. 1992. A Model of Growth through Creative Destruction. Econometrica, 60(2): 323–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion, P., P. Howitt, and G. Violante. 2002. General Purpose Technology and Wage Inequality. Journal of Economic Growth, 7(4): 315–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Autor, D., L. Katz, and M. Kearney. 2008. Trends in U.S. wage inequality: Re-assessing the revisionist. Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(2): 300–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R., and X. Sala-i-Martin. 1992. Convergence. Journal of Political Economy, 100(2): 223–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R., and X. Sala-i-Martin. 1997. Technological Diffusion, Convergence, and Growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 2(1): 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R., and X. Sala-i-Martin. 2004. Economic Growth, 2nd ed., Massachusetts: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bartel, A., and N. Sicherman. 1998. Technological Change and the Skill Acquisition of Young Workers. Journal of Labor Economics, 16(4): 718–755.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartel, A., and N. Sicherman. 1999. Technological Change and Wages: An Inter-Industry Analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 107(2): 285–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrman, J., N. Birdsall, and M. Szekely. 2000. Intergenerational Mobility in Latin America: Deeper Markets and Better Schools Make a Difference. New Markets, New Opportunities? Economic and Social Mobility in a Changing World. Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. Washington DC: Brookings Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caselli, F. 1999. Technological Revolutions. American Economic Review, 89(1): 78–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connolly, M. 2003. The Dual Nature of Trade: Measuring its IMpact on Imitation and Growth. Journal of Development Economics, 72(1): 31–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connolly, M., and D. Valderrama. 2007. North-South Technological Diffusion: A New Case for Dynamic Gains from Trade. San Francisco Federal Reserve Working Paper Series, 2004–2024.

  • Cornia, G. 2014. Falling Inequality in Latin America: Policy Changes and Lessons. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Das, S.P. 2002. Foreign Direct Investment and the Relative Wage in a Developing Country. Journal of Development Economics, 67(1): 55–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dinopoulos, E., and P. Segerstrom. 1999. A Schumpeterian Model of Protection and Relative Wages. American Economic Review, 89(3): 450–472.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dinopoulos, E., and P. Segerstrom. 2006. North-South Trade and Economic Growth. CEPR Discussion Papers 5887.

  • Duryea, S., and M. Szekely. 2000. Labor Markets in Latin America: A Look at the Supply-Side. Emerging Markets Review, 1(3): 199–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eicher, T., and S. Turnovsky. 2001. Transitional Dynamics in a Two-Sector Non-Scale Growth Model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 25(1–2): 85–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferguson, R. 1993. New Evidence on the Growing Value of Skill and Consequences for Racial Disparity and Return to Schooling. Harvard University, John F. Kennedy School of Government, Faculty Research Working Paper R93-94.

  • Galor, O., and O. Moav. 2000. Ability Biased Technological Transition, Wage Inequality and Economic Growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(2): 469–499.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., and D. Tsiddon. 1997. Technological Progress, Mobility, and Economic Growth. The American Economic Review, 87(3): 363–382.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood, J., and M. Yorukoglu. 1997. 1974. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 46, 49–95.

  • Grieben, W. 2005. A Schumpeterian North-South Growth Model of Trade and Wage Inequality. Review of International Economics, 13(1): 106–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z., and W. Mason. 1972. Education, Income, and Ability. Journal of Political Economy, 80(3): 74–103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G., and E. Helpman. 1991. Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. Massachusetts: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, J. 2013. The Rate of Technological Progress, Effective Human Capital and the Dynamics of Income Inequality: An Empirical Analysis. Working paper, available at “www.pages.drexel.edu/jdh56/research.htm”.

  • Hanson, G., and A. Harrison. 1999. Trade, Technology and Wage Inequality. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 52(2): 271–288.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek, E., and D. Kimko. 2000. Schooling, Labor-Force Quality, and the Growth of Nations. The American Economic Review, 90(5): 1184–1208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heston, A., R. Summers, and B. Aten. 2006. Penn World Table Version 6.2, Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University of Pennsylvania.

  • Kuznets, S. 1955. Economic Growth and Income Inequality. The American Economic Review, 45(1): 1–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lloyd-Ellis, H. 1999. Endogenous Technological Change and Wage Inequality. The American Economic Review, 89(1): 47–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Machin, S. 1996. Wage Inequality in the U.K. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 12(1): 47–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michaely, M., D. Papageorgiou, and A. Choksi. 1991. Liberalizing Foreign Trade: Lessons of Experience in the Developing World. Vol. 7. Basil, Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murnane, R., J. Willett, and F. Levy. 1995. The Growing Importance of Cognitive Skills in Wage Determination. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 77(2): 251–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quah, D. 1993. Empirical Cross-Section Dynamics in Economic Growth. European Economic Review, 37(2/3): 426–434.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ripoll, M. 2005. Trade Liberalization and the Skill Premium in Developing Economies. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52(3): 601–619.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robbins, D. 1996. Evidence on Trade and Wages in the Developing World. OECD Development Centre Technical Papers, 119.

  • Sala-i-Martin, X. 2006. The World Distribution of Income: Falling Poverty and … Convergence Period. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(2): 351–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sener, M. 2001. Schumpeterian Unemployment, Trade, and Wages. Journal of International Economics, 54(1): 119–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wood, A. 1994. North-South Trade, Employment and Inequality. Oxford: Claredon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wood, A. 1997. Openness and Wage Inequality in Developing Countries: The Latin American Challenge to East Asian Conventional Wisdom. The World Bank Economic Review, 11(1): 33–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zeira, J. 2007. Wage Inequality, Technology, and Trade. Journal of Economic Theory, 137(1): 79–103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhu, S.C., and D. Trefler. 2001. Ginis in General Equilibrium: Trade, Technology and Southern Inequality. NBER Working Paper No. 8446.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix

Appendix

Detailed equations

Northern and southern average profits

This Appendix provides more details for equations (15) and (16). Firms located in the North whose closest competitor is a Northern firm obtain a flow sum of domestic and export profits:

where Λ N =A N 1/(1−α)(α/q)1/(1−α), and is the average quality level on the frontier. Northern firms facing Southern competition, likewise, earn a sum of import and export profits:

where the size of the incremental quality increase, q, must be sufficiently large such the limit price exceeds the marginal cost of production. Average profits for intermediate firms in the North is:

where is the profits adjusted for the average quality level on the frontier. Trade barriers and the probability of innovation are embedded within A change in the rate of innovation and imitation, alter the effective levels of human capital (H N and H S ), the equilibrium relative price of the Southern final good and the distribution of firms (n NN , n NS , and n S ).

The partial effects of trade liberalization on the Northern average profits is given by:

Southern flow profits for intermediate producers are:

where Λ S =A S 1/(1−α)(α/q)1/(1−α), and, as in the North, is the quality adjusted profits for Southern imitators. I assume the Northern tariff is sufficiently low such that the export profits for Southern firms, given the limit price, is positive. Since only the state-of-the-art technology is used, any good produced in the South will still have the same quality level as the lead Northern quality frontier.

The partial effects of trade liberalization on the Northern average profits is given by:

Resources allocated to R&D

Using the two world resource constraints, the expressions for Z N and Z S from equations (26) and (27) are, in the North:

where

and in the South:

where

where χ N =C N /Q N and χ S =C S /Q N . and are the quality adjusted expenditures on R&D.

Balanced trade condition

The relative price of the Southern final good adjusts at each point of time to balance trade between the North and South. Expanding equation (30), implicitly solves:

where the partial effects of trade liberalization is given by:

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hall, J. Educational Quality Matters for Development: A Model of Trade, Inequality, and Endogenous Growth. Eastern Econ J 43, 128–154 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1057/eej.2015.40

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/eej.2015.40

Keywords

Keywords

Navigation